1 / 125

HKALE Macroeconomics

HKALE Macroeconomics. Chapter 2: Elementary Keynesian Model (I)- Two-sector. References:. CH 3, Advanced Level Macroeconomics, 5th Ed, Dr. LAM pun-lee, MacMillan Publishers (China) Limited CH 3, HKALE Macroeconomics, 2nd Ed., LEUNG man-por, Hung Fung Book Co. Ltd.

neil-mercer
Download Presentation

HKALE Macroeconomics

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. HKALE Macroeconomics Chapter 2: Elementary Keynesian Model (I)- Two-sector

  2. References: • CH 3, Advanced Level Macroeconomics, 5th Ed, Dr. LAM pun-lee, MacMillan Publishers (China) Limited • CH 3, HKALE Macroeconomics, 2nd Ed., LEUNG man-por, Hung Fung Book Co. Ltd. • CH 3, A-L Macroeconomics, 3rd Ed., Chan & Kwok, Golden Crown

  3. Introduction • National income accounting can only provide ex-post data about national income. • The three approaches are identities as they are true for any income level.

  4. Introduction • In order to explain the level and determinants of national income during a period of time, we count on national income determination model, e.g. Keynesian Models.

  5. Business Cycle GNP Recovery Boom Recession Depression 0 Time

  6. Business Cycle • It shows the recurrent fluctuations in GNP around a secular trend

  7. HK’s Economic Performance

  8. Assumptions behind National Income Models

  9. Assumptions behind National Income Models • The level of price is constant • as Y = P×Q & P = 1, then Y = (1)×Q Y = Q • Price level tends to be rigid in downward direction • Y = National income at constant price • Potential/Full-employment national income, Yf is constant • Existence of idle resources, i.e. unemployment

  10. Equilibrium Income Determination of Keynesian's Two-sector Model (1)- A SpendthriftEconomy

  11. John Maynard Keynes

  12. Assumptions • Two sectors: households and firms • no saving, no tax and no imports • no leakage/withdrawal • Y=Yd while Yd = disposable income • consumer goods only  no investment or injection

  13. National income National expenditure Simple Circular Flow Model of a Spendthrift Economy Households C Income generated Payment for goods and service Y E Firms

  14. By Income-expenditure Approach • AD → (without S) E = C → Y (firms) ↑ ↓ Y (households) ← AS ← D for factors

  15. By Income-expenditure Approach • Equilibrium income, Ye is determined when • AS = AD • Y = E Y = E = C

  16. Equilibrium Income Determination of Keynesian's Two-sector Model (2)-A Frugal Economy

  17. Assumptions 1. Households and firms 2. Saving, S, exists • Income is either consumed or saved Y ≡ C+S • leakage, S, exists 3. Without tax, Y=Yd

  18. Assumptions 4. Consumer and producer goods • Injection (investment, I) exist 5. Investment is autonomous/exogenous 6. Saving and investment decisions made separately • S=I occurs only at equilibriumlevel of income

  19. National income National expenditure Simple Circular Flow Model of a Frugal Economy Households C S Financial markets I Income generated Payment for goods and service Y E Firms

  20. E Y-line E2 E1 45 Y 0 Y1 Y2 Income Function: Income line/45 line/Y-line • an artificial linear function on which each point showing Y = E

  21. Expenditure Function (1): Consumption Function, C • showing that planned consumption expenditure varies positively with but proportionately less than change in Yd • A linear consumption function: C = a + cYd where • a = a constant representing autonomous consumption expenditure • c = Marginal Propensity to Consume, MPC

  22. C2 C1 Y2 Y1 A Consumption Function, C E C = a + cYd a Y 0

  23. E C = a + cYd M  △C △Y a Y 0 Marginal Propensity to Consume, MPC, c • MPC = c =

  24. Properties of MPC: • the slope of the consumption function • 1>MPC>0 • the value of 'c' is constant for all income levels

  25. E C = a + cYd M  C a Y 0 Y Average Propensity to Consume, APC • APC =

  26. Properties of APC: • the slope of the ray from the origin • APC falls when Y rises • Since C = a + cYd Then i.e. Thus, APC>MPC for all income levels

  27. E C = cYd <45 Y a = 0 Consumption Function Without ‘a” • If ‘a’ = 0, then C = cYd

  28. E C = cYd M  Y = △Y C = △C Y a = 0 Consumption Function Without ‘a” • If ‘a’ = 0, then MPC = APC =

  29. Expenditure Function (2): Investment Function, I • showing the relationship between planned investment expenditure and disposable income level, Yd

  30. E I = I* I* 0 Y Autonomous Investment Function • Autonomous investment function: I = I* where I* = a constant representing autonomous investment expenditure

  31. E I = I* + iYd I* 0 Y Induced Investment Function • Induced investment function: I = I* + iYd where i = Marginal Propensity to Invest = MPI =

  32. Properties of MPI: • the slope of the investment function • 1>MPI>0 • the value of ‘i' is constant for all income levels

  33. E I = I* + iYd M  I I* Y 0 Y Average Propensity to Invest, API • API =

  34. Properties of API: • the slope of the ray from the origin • API falls when Y rises • Since I = I* + iYd Then i.e. Thus, API>MPI for all income levels

  35. E I = I* I* 0 Y MPI under Autonomous Investment Function • If I = I*, then Y will not affect I • Therefore, MPI = Slope = MPI = 0

  36. Expenditure Function (3): Aggregate Expenditure Function, E • Showing the relationship between planned aggregate expenditure and disposable income level, Yd • Aggregate expenditure function: E = C+I

  37. Aggregate Expenditure Function, E • Since C = a + cYd I = I* (autonomous function) E = C+I • Then E = (a + cYd) + (I*)  E = (a + I*) + cYd Where • (a + I*) = a constant representing the intercept on the vertical axis • ‘c’ = slope of the E function

  38. Aggregate Expenditure Function, E • Since C = a + cYd I* + iYd(induced function) E = C+I • Then E = (a + cYd) + (I* + iYd)  E = (a + I*) + (c + i)Yd Where • (a + I*) = a constant representing the intercept on the vertical axis • ‘c + i’ = slope of the E function

  39. E E = C + I C = a + cYd E2 E1 (a+I*) a I = I* I* Y 0 Y1 Y2 Aggregate Expenditure Function

  40. E E = C + I C = a + cYd E2 E1 (a+I*) I = I*+iYd a I* Y 0 Y1 Y2 Aggregate Expenditure Function

  41. Leakage Function (1): Saving Function, S • showing that planned saving varies positively with but proportionately less than change in Yd • A linear saving function: S = -a + sYd where • -a = a constant = autonomous saving • s = Marginal Propensity to save, MPS

  42. S = -a + sYd E, S S2 -a S1 0 Y Y1 Y2 A Saving Function, S

  43. MPC (c) and MPS (s)

  44. E, S S = -a + sYd M  △S Y 0 △Y -a Marginal Propensity to Saving, MPS, s • MPS = s =

  45. Properties of MPS: • the slope of the saving function • 1>MPS>0 • the value of ‘s' is constant for all income levels • Since Y ≡ C + S Then Hence 1 = c + s and s = 1 - c

  46. E, S S = -a + sYd M  S Y 0 -a Y Average Propensity to Save, APS • APS =

  47. Properties of APS: • the slope of the ray from the origin • APS rises when Y rises • Since S = -a + sYd Then i.e. Thus, APS<MPS for all income levels

  48. E, S S = sYd -a = <45 Y 0 Saving Function Without ‘-a” • If ‘-a’ = 0, then S = sYd

  49. E, S S = sYd M  S = △S -a = Y 0 Y = △Y Saving Function Without ‘-a” • If ‘-a’ = 0, then MPS = APS =

  50. Determination of Ye by Income-expenditure Approach • Equilibrium income, Ye is determined when • AS = AD • Total Income = Total Expenditure i.e.Y = E = C + I Given C = a + cYd and I = I* Ye = Y and Yd = Y

More Related