1 / 41

What is the MPC?

What is the MPC?. Learning Objectives. Use linear regression to establish the relationship between two variables A more formal approach to hypothesis testing. Consumption Function. Keynesian Consumption function  income today,  consumption today C= a+b *Y

nell
Download Presentation

What is the MPC?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. What is the MPC?

  2. Learning Objectives • Use linear regression to establish the relationship between two variables • A more formal approach to hypothesis testing

  3. Consumption Function • Keynesian Consumption function •  income today,  consumption today • C=a+b*Y • Econometrics : quantify economic relationships • What are “a” and “b”

  4. Look at some data • Look at individual level data: individual.dta • Stata: scatter cons nmwage • This gives a scatter plot with the first variable on the vertical axis and the second variable on the x axis

  5. Look at data

  6. Two Obvious facts • Observe many households at different income levels • There is clearly a positive relationship • cons depends on income but households with same income will not have same consumption • other factors influence consumption

  7. How do we Calculate the MPC? • Draw a line • Many possible lines • Intuition tells us that an “average” line would be a better estimate • We will show why this intuition is correct later • Any line we draw (even the “best”) will not go through all the points • There will be deviations from the line

  8. Conditional Expectation • As an alternative to the line we could follow the logic of the gender example from the pervious section and look at conditional expectation • Recall we answered the question of gender discrimination by comparing the average wage of two groups • The expected waged conditional on being a man or woman • we used the “summ if” command • Formally • E(hwage|gender==1)=6.701875 • E(hwage|gender==2)=5.451302

  9. Conditional Expectation • We can apply the same logic to the consumption function. • Divide in two groups • Rich: nmwage>1000 • Poor:nmwage<1000 • generate rich=(nmwage>1000) • Compare the average consumption of each using summ if

  10. Conditional Expectation • We get average consumption conditional on being rich or poor • E(Cons|Rich)= 1297.3 • E(Cons|Poor)= 599.89 • We can measure the marginal propensity of consume by taking the average income of each group • E(nmwage|Rich)= 1611.698 • E(nmwag|Poor)= 711.9268

  11. Conditional Expectation • As you move from “poor” to “rich” your income rises by: • 1611 -711=900 • And consumption rises by: 1297-599=698 • So an estimate of the MPC would be 698/900 which is 0.77 • This is a simple and intuitive method that builds on the logic of the gender example • But…..

  12. Obvious Problem • The division between risk and poor was entirely arbitrary • Not natural like gender • We throw away information by forcing individuals into one group or another • Why not have 3 groups or any number of groups you like • Intuitively the more the better • 10 group example • But large numbers of groups would make calculations tedious and would always leave out some information

  13. 10 Income Groups

  14. Compromise • Imagine there are an infinity of groups but the conditional means are all related • Specifically they have a linear relationship • E(cons|nmwage)=a+b*nmwage • From now on we will write in more general notation • E(Y|X)=b1+b2X

  15. Comment • Note this is a restriction and it may not be true in the real world • We impose it on the model • Looks reasonable in the consumption example • If it isn't true then there might be a problem • Linear approx • GIGO • Relationship doesn’t have to be linear but it does have to be parametric • We will see more on this later

  16. So to Recap… • We have data that appears to illustrate a relationship between two variables • Intuitively we will put a line through the data that represents the data in some way • What way? Two ways: • the line links all the conditional means • We choose the particular line that is closest to the data in a defined way • These turn out to be the same

  17. Draw a line to represent the data Show three data points for illustration

  18. An Explanation • Change in notation to be more general • Y is the LHS or dependent variable • X is the RHS or independent variable • E(Y|Xi) = conditional mean i.e. does not describe every observation • Yi = E(Y|Xi) +ui • uirepresents the deviation of each individual observation from the conditional mean • Yi= E(Y|Xi) + ui • Yi = 1+2 Xi+ ui

  19. What is Ui? • Any factor other than income (X) which influences consumption (Y) • individual tastes and unpredictability • approximation error because of assumption of linear relationship • Later we will model this a random variable • Perhaps with a normal distribution • Remember our warnings about the bell curve

  20. OLS Estimation • Find line of “best fit” • Method of Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) to estimate 12 • Objective: find estimates of 12 that minimizes the distance between the regression line and the actual data points, i.e. minimize the error terms • Minimisethe sum of squared deviations i.e. • Aside: why not absolute deviation or others?

  21. Algebra of OLS • min i ui2 i.e. min (u12 + u22+u32+…+ui2) • Yi = 1+2Xi+ui => ui = Yi - 1+2X • i ui2 = i (Yi - 1+2X)2 = S(1 , 2) • => sum of squared errors is a function of 1 , 2 • min S(1 , 2) = min i (Yi - 1+2X)2

  22. To find minimum of any function: differentiate with respect to the arguments and set derivative = 0 i.e. find the point where the slope with respect to the argument = 0.

  23. An Explanation • b1, b2 are the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) estimators of the true population parameters 1 , 2. • b2 is the estimator of the slope coefficient: the slope coefficient measures the effect on y of a one unit change in x • b1 is the estimator of the intercept: the value of Y which occurs if X=0;

  24. OLS in stata i ui2 regress cons nmwage Source | SS df MS Number of obs = 1330 -------------+------------------------------ F( 1, 1328) = 605.97 Model | 98124170.1 1 98124170.1 Prob > F = 0.0000 Residual | 215041332 1328 161928.714 R-squared = 0.3133 -------------+------------------------------ Adj R-squared = 0.3128 Total | 313165502 1329 235639.956 Root MSE = 402.4 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ cons | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- nmwage | .7562304 .0307205 24.62 0.000 .6959644 .8164964 _cons | 62.47876 25.9165 2.41 0.016 11.63701 113.3205 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ Estimated coef

  25. The Answer • The regression gives us a measure of the MPC • The OLS estimate of the MPC is 0.756 • What use is this • Prediction • Causation • Statistical inference

  26. Prediction • We can use this to make predictions • What would the consumption be if income were 2500 • Cons=62.47876 + 0.7562304*2500 • This is equal to 1953 • Be careful this is the predicted conditional mean • It is the next point on the line • What people with 2500 would consume on average • What they actually will consume is unknown because we don’t observe their Ui

  27. Predicted Consumption Actual Consumption Predicted Cons

  28. Causation • Remember all this only really identifies variables that move together • It doesn’t show causation • Need theory for that • Obvious in the gender example (wages don’t cause changes in gender) • Not obvious here causation can run both ways

  29. Statistical Inference • This estimate is generated from a sample • Recall that the issue is whether we can use this fact about the sample to make statements about the world (“population”) • The same issues of statistical inference arise in context of regression • OLS estimates are sample statistics just like the sample average wages in the gender example

  30. More on the Residual (Ui) • The residual is the difference between the line (conditional expectation) and the actual data • Think of every individuals consumption as being made up of two bits • Conditional expectation • Residual • The conditional expectation is that same for everyone with the same X (income) • Residual is potentially different even for those with same income

  31. Random Variable • Residual is unknown in advance so we model it as a random variable • Think of consumption being determined by systematic bit plus a roll of a dice • See diagram • Actual consumption (expectation+residual) is distributed around the mean • All the means are linked

  32. Each distribution is a slice in the data

  33. Distribution of Y for two different “slices” of X

  34. Empirical Distribution • We can use the histcomand in stata to look at this • Just as we got distribution of hwage for men and women • hist cons, by(rich) norm • We could do the same for any income group • hist cons if nmwage<1100 &nmwage >900, norm • All OLS does is draw a line through all the means • Imagine laying all these distributions side by side

  35. The “Slice” Around nmwage=1000

  36. Linking the Means • We assume that there is a linear relationship between the means of all these distributions • Imagine taking each and lining them up in order of their average • Get the next diagram

  37. Distribution of Y

  38. Putting it all together • We usually assume that the residual is a normal random variable • Seems reasonable in this case • But remember our concerns about normal • So the full model is • Yi = 1+2 Xi + ui • WhereE(Y|Xi)= 1+2 Xi • And ui~N(0,s2)

More Related