1 / 32

Term Structure Driven by general L é vy processes

Term Structure Driven by general L é vy processes Bonaventure Ho HKUST, Math Dept. Oct 6, 2005 Outline Why do we need to model term structure? Going from Brownian motion to L évy process Model assumption and bond price dynamics Markovian short rate and stationary volatility structure

oshin
Download Presentation

Term Structure Driven by general L é vy processes

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Term Structure Driven by general Lévy processes Bonaventure Ho HKUST, Math Dept. Oct 6, 2005

  2. Outline • Why do we need to model term structure? • Going from Brownian motion to Lévy process • Model assumption and bond price dynamics • Markovian short rate and stationary volatility structure • Comparison between Gaussian and Lévy setting • Conclusion and Discussion

  3. Why do we need to model term structure? • Term structure is the information contained in the forward rate curve, short rate curve, and yield curve observed from market data. • There are deterministic relationships among forward rates (f), short rates (instantaneous interest rate)(r) and zero-coupon bond prices (P). • Usually, a model on fixed income assumes certain dynamics on the zero-coupon bond (eg. HJM) or on forward rates (eg. LIBOR). One can calculate the model price for f, r, and P under this model. • Arbitrage opportunities arise when the predicted values for f, r, or P are different from the currently observed market data. • Therefore, an arbitrage-free model should incorporate the term structure into itself.

  4. History of the Gaussian model • No-arbitrage  Existence of risk neutral measure • What is risk neutral measure? • An equivalent probability measure under which all tradable securities, when discounted, are martingales. • Discount factor (numeraire) = • Log-normal model • Initiated by Bachelier (1900), modeling the French government bonds using Brownian motion. • Samuelson (1965) gave the price process in exponential form • Black and Scholes (1973) framework of log-normality of stock prices • Eg.) Heath-Jarrow-Morton model under the risk neutral measure where W is a standard Brownian motion • Major shortcomings • Cannot generate volatility smile/skew as shown in the market data • Distribution itself does not fit the market data very well – fatter tail and high peak, jump!

  5. Lévy Process • Lévy process Lt – a generalization to the Brownian motion. • stochastic process with stationary and independent increments • continuous in probability (P(|Lu -Lv|≥ε)  0, as u  v for all v) • L0=0 a.s. • viewed as Brownian motion with jump • associated Lévy measure F • characterized by (,,F) for drift, variance, and the Lévy measure for jump • Examples of Lévy processes • Brownian motion W • BM with jump • (Merton) Merton Jump Part (Compound Poisson jump) • (Carr) Variance Gamma • (Eberlein) Hyperbolic (used as an example in the paper)

  6. Examples of Lévy Processes Remarks: K1 is the modified Bessel function of the third kind with index 1

  7. Motivation to use Lévy processes • To incorporate jump into the price dynamics. • Merton (1976) added an independent Poisson jump process with normal jump size. • Eberlein (author of the presenting paper) and Keller • “It is in certain way opposite to the Brownian world, since its (Lévy process) paths are purely discontinuous. If one looks at real stock price movements on the intraday scale it is exactly this discontinuous behavior what one observes.”– Eberlein and Keller (1997), promoting the hyperbolic Lévy model. • In 1995, they performed empirical studies and revealed a much better fit of return distributions on stock prices if the Brownian motion is replaced by a Lévy process. However, evidence for non-Gaussian behavior on bond prices is not as complete. • In 2005, Eberlein & Özkan explore the LIBOR model using Lévy processes. • Volatility smile/skew cannot be generated by the log-normal model • Jump and/or stochastic volatility can generate such smile/skew. • I will discuss the “jump” part as a component of Lévy processes in this presentation, based mostly on the paper by Eberlein and Raible. • Stochastic volatility can be generated by the “time-change” method, which will be my research topic. Idea: change the calendar time to a random “business-activity” clock.

  8. Model assumptions • (initial bond prices)P(0,T) is deterministic, positive, and twice continuously differentiable function in T for all T[0,T*] for a fixed time horizon T* • (boundary condition)P(T,T)=1 for all T[0,T*] • (volatility bounds)Define :={(s,T) : 0sT T*}(s,T)>0 for all (s,T), sT, and (T,T)=0 for all T[0,T*] • (integrability)There exists constants M, >0 such that • (volatility smoothness)(s,T), defined on , is twice continuously differentiable in both variables and is bounded by M from #4

  9. Bond price dynamics • In HJM model, the solution to the SDE is simply • Note that the above solution of the SDE is evaluated under the risk neutral measure. • Our generalization: • Replace W by L, thus source of randomness = • Replace the discount factor by a more general numéraire :(t) Under this numéraire, P(t,T) is a martingale under this measure when expressed in terms of units of (t).

  10. Basic Lemmas(1) • Lemma 1.1 If f is left-continuous with limits from the right and bounded by M, then where denotes the log MGF of L1 • In particular, take f to be , we have • Here we relate the expected value of the source of randomness to the log MGF of the Lévy process, which is known when the process is specified. Proof

  11. Basic Lemmas(2) • Lemma 1.2 Forward rate process f(,T) has the form where 2 denotes the partial derivative of  in its second variable (T) • Lemma 1.3 Thenuméraire (t) is given by , where (t) is the usual money market account process Remark: Substituting the result back to our initial assumption, we obtainFor Gaussian model, (u)=u2/2, we obtain the usual case Proof Proof

  12. Term structure of the volatility • We want to explore the class of volatility structure so that the short rate process is Markovian. • Furthermore, we want to restrict our volatility structure to be stationary. That is,  . • It will be proven that the volatility has either Vasiček volatility structure or Ho-Lee volatility structure! or for real constants

  13. Proof steps(1) • Lemma 2.1 Suppose the CF of L1 is bounded, with real constants C, , >0, such that If f, g are continuous functions such that f(s)k·g(s) for all s, then the joint distribution of X and Y is continuous w.r.t. Lebesgue measure 2 on 2, where • Lemma 2.2 The short rate process r is Markovian if and only if where 0<T<U<T*, and note that  may depend on T and U, but not on t. • Corollary: Proof Proof

  14. Proof steps(2) & Hull-White revisit • Theorem 2.3 Further assume that the volatility structure is stationary, then it must be either of Vasiček or Ho-Lee structure. • Corollary Under the above stationarity and Markovian assumptions, we can take the volatility to have the Vasiček volatility structure. Then the short rate process follows: If we take L to be W, we revert back to the Hull-White model (or the extended Vasiček model) Proof

  15. Comparing forward rates • Using similar steps, we can derive the forward rate process. • Comparing it to the Gaussian case, we obtain:

  16. Examples using Lévy processes (hyperbolic) • Eberlein and Keller (1995) used hyperbolic Lévy motion to model stock price dynamics. They claimed that the hyperbolic model allows an almost perfect statistical fit of stock return data. • In order to compare with the Gaussian case, we restrict L1 to be centered, symmetric, and with unit variance. That is, we pick K1 and K2 denotes the modified Bessel function of the third kind with index 1 and 2 respectively. • We investigate the case =10 (density close to normal) and =0.01 (considerably heavier weight in the tails and in the center than normal). • Vasiček volatility structure, • Initial term structure: flat at f(0,t)=0.05 for all t

  17. Hyperbolic, =0.01 Hyperbolic, =10 Standard normal Hyperbolic vs normal

  18. Comparing forward rates Figure 1: Forward rate predicted by hyperbolic Lévy (=0.01) Figure 2: fhyper(t,T)-fGauss(t,T) Forward rates predicted by hyperbolic Lévy motion are marginally higher than that predicted by Brownian motion.

  19. Comparing bond options Bond call option: current time = 0, option maturity = t, bond maturity = T, strike = K In the Gaussian case, there is an analytic solution: However, in the Lévy setting, the expectation becomes: Fortunately, a numerical solution is available because the joint density function for the last two stochastic terms can be found. (Very complicated) Comparison method: We compare the pricing difference against the various forward price/strike price ratio. Option maturity = 1yr, bond maturity = 2yr Note that at-the-money strike  0.951

  20. Comparing bond options result Figure 3 Differences in option pricing vs forward/strike price ratio As one can see, for =10, the difference is minimal, but for =0.01, At-the-money option is lower for the hyperbolic model (~10%) while the in-the-money and out-of-the-money prices are slightly higher, forming the W-shaped pattern as show in Figure 3.

  21. Conclusion • Lévy process – a generalization to Brownian motion that allows jumps, which is more realistic to model bond/stock price movements. • Under the assumption of Markovian short rate and stationary volatility structure, the only possible volatility structures are Ho-Lee and Vasiček. • We can re-derive the mean-reverting short rate process (Hull-White) when we utilize Vasiček volatility even under Lévy process. • When we use hyperbolic model, forward rates predicted by Lévy model is always slightly higher than the Gaussian model. • For bond option, the price differences form a W-shaped against the forward/strike price ratio, due to heavier weight in the center and in the tail for the hyperbolic distribution.

  22. Discussion • Future research on time-changed Lévy process, which can capture both jump and stochastic volatility. • Apply time-changed Lévy process to the LIBOR model and explore the term structure under the model. • Apply time-changed Lévy process to model stock/bond price movement for option pricing with correlation, or to model firm value movement for credit derivative pricing (for structural model evaluation)

  23. References Carr, P. G´eman, H., Madan, D., Wu, L., Yor, M. (2003) Option Pricing using Integral Transforms. Stanford Financial Mathematics Seminar (Winter 2003). Carr, P., Wu, L. (2003) Time-Changed Lévy Processes and Option Pricing. Journal of Financial Economics, Elsevier, Vol 71(1), 113-141. Eberlein, E., Baible, S. (1999). Term structure models driven by general Lévy processes. Mathematical Finance, Vol 9(1), 31-53. Eberlein, E., Keller, U. (1995). Hyperbolic distributions in finance. Bernoulli, 1, 281-299. Eberlein, E., Keller, U., Prause, K. (1998)New insights into smile, mispricing and value at risk: the hyperbolic model. Journal of Business 71. Eberlein, E., Özkan, F. (2005) The Lévy Libor Model. Finance and Stochastics 9, 327-348.

  24. THE END Thank you for participating.

  25. Appendix • Appendix 1.1 BACK

  26. Appendix • Appendix 1.2 From (1), and lemma 1.1, Take –log, we get, Differentiate w.r.t. T, we have, BACK

  27. Appendix • Appendix 1.3 From (1), and lemma 1.1, From (2), setting tT Integrate r(T), BACK

  28. Appendix • Appendix 2.2 From (2), we can see that r is Markov iff Z(T) is Markov, where () Assume r is Markov. Then is independent of because of the independent increments of L. Thus the last two terms are equal, implying the equality of the first two terms. BACK

  29. Appendix • Appendix 2.2 (con’t) However is measurable w.r.t. . Therefore, is some function of Z(T), say . Then the joint distribution of X and Y, where is only defined on (x,G(x)), thus can’t be continuous w.r.t. 2 on 2. By lemma 2.1, BACK

  30. Appendix • Appendix 2.2 (con’t) () Assume , then BACK

  31. Appendix • Appendix 2.2 (con’t) For the corollary, simply take U=T*, then we have 2(t,T*)=  2(t,T), where  is independent of t (yet it may depend on T and T*). If =0, then 2(t,T*)=0 for all t. However, this implies that (t,T)=constant for all T, which violates the assumption that (t,T)>0 for tT and (t,t)=0. Therefore,   0. Then we can define and obtain our desired result, where BACK

  32. Appendix • Appendix 2.3 Write . Then . Writing we have Rearranging terms, we have Since both sides cannot depend on t or T, it must equal to some constant a. If a=0, then (Ho-Lee) If a0, then (Vasiček) BACK

More Related