250 likes | 261 Views
Explore constant-factor approximation algorithms for identifying dynamic communities in evolving networks. Analyze group interactions, community definitions, and optimization problems with real-world examples. Proposed solutions provide fast and near-optimal community identification.
E N D
Constant-Factor Approximation Algorithms for Identifying Dynamic Communities Chayant Tantipathananandh with Tanya Berger-Wolf
Social Networks These are snapshots and networks change over time
Dynamic Networks t=1 t=1 3 5 4 1 2 t=2 1 … 3 2 t=2 5 2 3 4 1 5 2 4 1 … 5 2 3 4 4 5 5 2 4 1 3 Aggregated network 1 1 2 2 3 5 2 3 • Interactions occur in the form of disjoint groups • Groups are not communities 1 1 4
Communities • What is community? “Cohesive subgroups are subsets of actors among whom there are relatively strong, direct, intense, frequent, or positive ties.” [Wasserman & Faust 1994] • Dynamic Community Identification • GraphScope [Sun et al 2005] • Metagroups [Berger-Wolf & Saia 2006] • Dynamic Communities [TBK 2007] • Clique Percolation [Palla et al 2007] • FacetNet [Lin et al 2009] • Bayesian approach [Yang et al 2009]
Ship of Theseus from Wikipedia “The ship … was preserved by the Athenians …, for they took away the old planks as they decayed, putting in new and stronger timber in their place, insomuch that this ship became a standing example among the philosophers, for the logical question of things that grow; one side holding that the ship remained the same, and the other contending that it was not the same.” [Plutarch, Theseus] Jeannot's knife “has had its blade changed fifteen times and its handle fifteen times, but is still the same knife.” [French story]
Ship of Theseus Individual parts never change identities Cost for changing identity …
Ship of Theseus Identity changes to match the group Costs for visiting and being absent …
Community = Color Valid coloring: In each time step, different groups have different colors.
Interpretation Group color: How does community c interact at time t?
Interpretation Individual color: Who belong to community c at time t? 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 1
Social Costs: Conservatism Switching cost α 2 2 α α 2 2 α α 2 2 2 2 α α 2 2 Absence cost β1 Visiting cost β2
Social Costs: Loyalty 3 3 β1 β1 β1 2 3 2 3 β1 β1 1 1 β1 β1 Switching cost α Absence cost β1 Visiting cost β2
Social Costs: Loyalty β2 3 β2 3 β2 2 β2 2 Switching cost α Absence cost β1 Visiting cost β2
Problem Complexity • Minimizing total cost is hardNP-complete and APX-hard [with Berger-Wolf and Kempe 2007] • Constant-Factor Approximation [details in paper] • Easy special caseIf no missing individuals and 2α ≤ β2 , thensimply weighted bipartite matching[details in paper]
Greedy Approximation No visiting or absence and minimizing switching time
Greedy Approximation No visiting or absence and minimizing switching 3 4 2 ≈ maximizing path coverage 3 Greedy alg guaranteesmax{2, 2α/β1, 4α/β2} in α, β1, β2, independent of input size 7 2 3 4 Improvementby dynamic programming 3 time
Southern Women Data Set [DGG 1941] • 18 individuals, 14 time steps • Collected in Natchez, MS, 1935 aggregated network
Ethnography [DGG1941] Core Core note: columns not ordered by time
Optimal Communities individuals time Core Core ethnography all costs equal white circles = unknown
Approximate Optimal time time ethnography Core Core Core Core
Approximation Power 28 inds, 44 times 29 inds, 82 times 313 inds, 758 times
Approximation Power 41 inds, 418 times 264 inds, 425 times 96 inds, 1577 times
Conclusions • Identity of objects that change over time (Ship of Theseus Paradox) • Formulate an optimization problem • Greedy approximation • Fast • Near-optimal • Future Work • Algorithm with guarantee not depending on α, β1, β2 • Network snapshots instead of disjoint groups
Thank You NSF grant, KDD student travel award Mayank Lahiri Chayant Jared Saia David Kempe Arun Maiya Ilya Fischoff Habiba Saad Sheikh Tanya Berger-Wolf Dan Rubenstein Anushka Anand Siva Sundaresan Rajmonda Sulo Robert Grossman