1 / 45

Econ 522 Economics of Law

Econ 522 Economics of Law. Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 16. Reminders. HW3 (contract law) due next Thursday. Results of Monday’s Experiment (trust). The game we played. Player A starts with $5 Chooses how much of it to give to player B That money is quadrupled

ryder
Download Presentation

Econ 522 Economics of Law

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Econ 522Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 16

  2. Reminders • HW3 (contract law) due next Thursday

  3. Results of Monday’s Experiment (trust)

  4. The game we played • Player A starts with $5 • Chooses how much of it to give to player B • That money is quadrupled • Player B has $5, plus 4x whatever A gave him/her • Chooses how much (if any) to give back to player A • Tried it four ways: • Anonymous • On paper, but with names • Face to face • Openly in front of the class

  5. What is subgame perfect equilibrium? • No matter what player A does, B is best off keeping everything • So A is best off sending nothing • So subgame perfect equilibrium payoffs are ($5, $5), even though total surplus of $25 could be achieved through cooperation • So how did you guys do?

  6. How’d you guys do? A sent Observations Average back from B Fraction who got 0 0 10 1.00 80% 1 4 3.00 25% 2 10 1.70 40% ANONYMOUS 3 10 6.30 0% 4 5 9.40 20% 5 24 8.96 8% 84% sent something avg sent $3.66 avg gain $3.02 15% got 0 back A sent Observations Average back from B Fraction who got 0 0 4 0.00 100% 1 3 4.70 0% 2 9 3.00 0% WITH NAMES 3 9 6.80 0% 4 6 6.00 0% 5 34 10.80 6% 94% sent something avg sent $3.97 avg gain $4.34 3% got 0 back

  7. So, is trust a problem? • With anonymity, yes • Average A sent $3.08, got back $5.78 • Trust was rewarded, but there was some risk • Of those A’s who sent something, 15% got nothing back, 19% got back less than they sent • Worse, only about 60% of the potential gains were realized • 16% of A’s sent nothing, only 38% sent 5 • Things got better with names • Average A sent $3.72, got back $7.79 • Only 6% of A’s sent nothing, 52% sent 5 • Of those who sent something… • only 3% got nothing back, and only 8% lost money • 74% got back at least twice as much as they sent

  8. So, is trust a problem? • Face to face or in public: no problem at all • Every single A who traded face-to-face or in public sent the maximum amount, and every B sent back between $10 and $13 • But trust was an issue in “anonymous” trading • Trust was rewarded, but with some risk… • …and not everyone was willing to trust, leading to some gains going unrealized

  9. Back to work

  10. Paradox of compensation Expectation damages include benefit from reliance investments Expectation damages exclude benefit from reliance investments • Efficient breach • Efficient investment in performance • Over-reliance • Inefficient breach • Underinvestment in performance • Efficient reliance • Is there a way to get efficient behavior by both parties? Skip

  11. We already saw one possible solution • Have expectation damages include benefit from reliance… • …but only up to the efficient level of reliance, not beyond • That is, have damages reward efficient reliance investments, but not overreliance • Promisee has no incentive to over-rely  efficient reliance • Promisor still bears full cost of breach  efficient performance • Problem: this requires court to calculate efficient level of reliance after the fact

  12. Another clever (but unrealistic) solution • The problem: • Damages promisor pays should include gain from reliance if we want to get efficient performance • Damages promisee receives should exclude gain from reliance if we want to get efficient reliance • Solution: make damages promisor pays different from damages promisee receives! • How do we do this? Need a third party

  13. “Anti-insurance” • You (promisee) and I (promisor) offer Bob this deal: • If you rely and I breach, • I pay Bob value of promise with reliance (airplane plus hangar) • Bob pays you value of promise without reliance (airplane alone) • Bob keeps the difference • You receive damages without benefit from reliance; I pay damages with benefit from reliance

  14. “Anti-insurance” • You (promisee) and I (promisor) offer Bob this deal: • If you rely and I breach, • I pay Bob value of promise with reliance (airplane plus hangar) • Bob pays you value of promise without reliance (airplane alone) • Bob keeps the difference • You receive damages without benefit from reliance;I pay damages with benefit from reliance • Offer the deal to two people, make them pay up front for it

  15. Reminder: what do courts actually do? • Foreseeable reliance • Include benefits reliance that promisor could have reasonably anticipated

  16. Repeatedinteractions

  17. Repeated games

  18. Repeated games Player 1 (you) Trust me Don’t Player 2 (me) (100, 0) Share profits Keep all the money (150, 50) (0, 200) • Suppose we’ll play the game over and over • After each game, 10% chance relationship ends, 90% chance we play at least once more…

  19. Repeated games • Suppose you’ve chosen to trust me • Keep all the money: I get $200 today, nothing ever again • Share profits: I get $50 today, $50 tomorrow, $50 day after… • Value of relationship = • Since this is more than $200, we can get cooperation

  20. Repeated games • Suppose you’ve chosen to trust me • Keep all the money: I get $200 today, nothing ever again • Share profits: I get $50 today, $50 tomorrow, $50 day after… • Value of relationship = • Since this is more than $200, we can get cooperation

  21. Repeated games and reputation • Diamond dealers in New York (Friedman) “…people routinely exchange large sums of money for envelopes containing lots of little stones without first inspecting, weighing, and testing each one” “Parties to a contract agree in advance to arbitration;if… one of them refuses to accept the arbitrator’s verdict, he is no longer a diamond merchant – because everyone in the industry now knows he cannot be trusted.”

  22. Repeated games and reputation • The first purpose of contract law is to enable cooperation, by converting games with noncooperative solutions into games with cooperative solutions • The sixth purpose of contract law is to foster enduring relationships, which solve the problem of cooperation with less reliance on courts to enforce contracts • Law assigns legal duties to certain long-term relationships • Bank has fiduciary duty to depositors • McDonalds franchisee has certain duties to franchisor

  23. Repeated games and the endgame problem • Suppose we’ll play agency game 60 times • $50 x 60 = $3,000 > $200, so cooperation seems like no problem • But… • In game #60, reputation has no value to me • Last time we’re going to interact • So I have no reason not to keep all the money • So you have no reason to trust me • But if we weren’t going to cooperate in game #60, then in game #59…

  24. Repeated games and the endgame problem • Endgame problem: once there’s a definite end to our relationship, no reason to trust each other • Example: collapse of communism in late 1980s • Communism believed to be much less efficient than capitalism • But fall of communism led to decrease in growth • Under communism, lots of production relied on gray market • Transactions weren’t protected by law, so they relied on long-term relationships • Fall of communism upset these relationships

  25. One other bitI like from Friedman

  26. Friedman on premarital sex

  27. Friedman on premarital sex

  28. That’s it for contract law • Purposes for contract law: • Encourage cooperation • Encourage efficient disclosure of information • Secure optimal commitment to performance • Secure efficient reliance • Provide efficient default rules and regulations • Foster enduring relationships • Next up: tort law

  29. But first, let’s recapour story so far…

  30. Our story so far • Efficiency • Maximizing total surplus realized by everyone in society • Scarce resources are owned by whoever values them most • Actions are taken if social benefit exceeds social cost • Design a legal system that leads to efficient outcomes • Once we set up the rules, we don’t expect people to act based on what’s efficient • We expect people to do whatever’s in their own best interest • So the goal is set up the rules such that people acting in their own best interest will naturally lead to efficiency

  31. Our story so far • Coase gives us one way to do that • If property rights are clearly defined and tradable, and there are no transaction costs, people have incentive to trade until each resource is efficiently owned • So initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency • But if there are transaction costs, we may not get efficiency this way • Led us to two normative views of the legal system: • 1. Minimize transaction costs (“lubricate” private exchange) • 2. Allocate rights as efficiently as possible • Tradeoff between injunctive relief and damages

  32. Our story so far • Property law works well for simultaneous trade • Contracts allow for non-simultaneous trade • Contract law can… • Enable cooperation • Encourage efficient disclosure of information • Secure optimal commitment to performance • Secure efficient reliance • Supply efficient default rules and regulations • Foster enduring relationships

  33. Our story so far • So far, we’ve been talking about voluntary exchange • Coase is predicated on exchange being voluntary for both parties • Contracts are an extension of voluntary trade • Up next: “involuntary trade” • You’re bicycling to class, I’m texting while driving and I hit you • You didn’t want to deal with me, I didn’t want to deal with you…

  34. Our story so far • To put it another way… • Property law covers situations where transaction costs are low enough to get agreement ahead of time • Exceptions to property law – private necessity, eminent domain – when this isn’t the case • Contract law covers situations when transaction costs are low enough for us to agree to a contract, high enough that we may not want to renegotiate the contract later • Tort law covers situations where transaction costs are too high to agree to anything in advance

  35. Tort law

  36. An example

  37. An example • punish the choice • criminal law • regulations Choice + Bad Luck  Outcome

  38. An example • punish the choice • criminal law • regulations • punish the outcome • “strict liability” Choice + Bad Luck  Outcome • punish the combination of choice and outcome • “negligence”

  39. Tort law • Tort, noun. from French word meaning injury • Contract law: situations where someone harms you by breaking a promise they had made • Tort law: situations where someone harms you without having made any promises • “If someone shoots you, you call a cop. If he runs his car into yours, you call a lawyer.”

  40. As always, we’ll be focused on achieving efficiency • I hit you with my car, do $1,000 worth of damage • You’re $1,000 worse off • (No damage to me or my car) • Should I have to pay you damages? I owe nothing I owe $1,000 I owe $50,000 Your payoff –1,000 0 49,000 My payoff 0 –1,000 –50,000 Combined payoffs –1,000 –1,000 –1,000

  41. Something to remember distributionbut notefficiency efficiency

  42. Tort law • Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes? • Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law) • Accidental harms: trickier • Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents”

  43. Tort law • Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes? • Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law) • Accidental harms: trickier • Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents” • Unlike nuisance law, injunctive relief is not an option • Unlike contract law, no agreement ahead of time • Cooter and Ulen: essence of tort law is “the attempt to make injurers internalize the externalities they cause, in situations where transaction costs are too high to do this through property or contract rights”

  44. Cast of characters • Plaintiff – person who brings a lawsuit • Defendant – person who is being sued • In a nuisance case, the defendant caused a nuisance, plaintiff was bothered by it, might be asking for injunction or damages • In a contract case, defendant breached a contract or violated its terms • In a tort case, defendant caused some harm to plaintiff, plaintiff is asking for damages • Plaintiff is the victim (person who was harmed) • Defendant is the injurer (person who caused the harm) 43

  45. Next week • “Classic” legal theory of torts • Simple economic model to study incentives 44

More Related