210 likes | 384 Views
Direct job creation policies in the aftermath of the great recession. David Neumark. Great Recession slowed job growth…. … and led to dramatic increase in unemployment rate. Hiring credits and worker subsidies as tools of job creation.
E N D
Direct job creation policies in the aftermath of the great recession David Neumark
Hiring credits and worker subsidies as tools of job creation • Two types of policies with the simplest and most direct impact on the number of workers employed in the state • Subsidies to employers to hire workers (“hiring credits”) • Intended to increase demand for labor, by lowering cost of workers • Subsidies to individuals to enter the labor market (“worker subsidies”) • Intended to increase supply of labor, by increasing return to work
Other policies proposed—less direct, uncertain, and likely more expensive effects • Federal ARRA • State level tax reductions/exemptions, regulatory and tort reform, High Speed Rail, other infrastructure investment • “Indirect,” change economic incentives, but don’t directly target increases in employment • E.g., subsidizing other business costs, such as capital investment, may increase employment, but lowering prices of other inputs could lead firms to substitute away from labor • Policies that favor businesses generally should help them grow, but don’t necessarily reduce cost of labor, so cost/job created may be very high • Consistent with job creation costs of ARRA discussed later • Policies favoring particular industries subject may reflect political power more than job creation potential
Most hiring credits target specific workers • Federal programs have tended to target the disadvantaged • Recent HIRE Act an exception—targets unemployed • States programs vary widely • Many focus on recently unemployed • Fewer focus on disadvantaged • California’s current program: New Jobs Credit • Enacted 2009 • Targets small businesses generally • Enterprise zones a little different—geographically targeted
Wage (w) S(w) D’(w(1−c)) D(w) Employment (E(w)) Hiring credits Hiring credit = c, simplified Credit reduces wage paid by firms, so they demand more labor at any market wage
Theory is simple, but reality is more complex • Stigma effects • Eligibility for credit sends negative signals to employers • Large administrative costs • Employer windfalls • Pay for hiring that would have occurred anyway • Need to create incentives for new hiring • Always a problem with hiring credits • Evidence suggests that for credits targeting the disadvantaged, these problems are serious, and generally make hiring credits ineffective
Additional problems arise for enterprise zone hiring credits • Much effort devoted to activities other than direct job creation • Retroactive claiming (in California) for hires up to four years ago • Cross-vouchering (eliminated in 2006) • Evidence points to no effects on employment in California • Similar evidence for other areas—but not all—concurs
Credits targeting the unemployed may work better • Mid-1970s program a model (New Jobs Tax Credit) • General, did not target disadvantaged workers (but created greater incentives to hire low-skill workers) • Incentivized net job creation (firms had to grow by 2% or more) • Temporary • Evidence indicates NJTC may have created more than 500,000 jobs • Evidence from national policy is less decisive • 30+ years ago, so risky to extrapolate
EITC is primary example of worker subsidy • Federal EITC provides incentives to enter the workforce • Offers wage supplements based on family size • Phases out as earnings increase • Many states have own EITC as add-on to federal program • California has proposed but never enacted its own EITC
Wage (w) S(w) S’’(w(1+e)) D(w) Employment (E(w)) Worker subsidies Worker subsidy = e, simplified Subsidy increases wage earned by workers, so they supply more labor at any market wage
EITC increases employment • EITC boosts employment among single mothers • 18-23% increase for low-skill single mothers after federal expansion • State programs also show strong gains • But work disincentives created by phase-out of EITC • Small reduction in hours worked among other groups • Overall employment increases strongly offset any hours reductions • Effective at targeting low-income families
Usual conclusion: worker subsidies (EITC) more effective • Avoids stigma effects • Low administrative costs • Better targets poor and low-income families • Evidence on positive employment effects is more compelling
But key short-run policy recommendation is to use hiring credits targeting the unemployed • Evidence of ineffectiveness comes mainly from hiring credits for the disadvantaged • In current context we would focus more on the unemployed generally, more like NJTC • Focus on the unemployed would reduce stigma effects, and current threat of windfalls is low, so eligibility could be simple and administrative burden low • Assuming that Great Recession is demand driven, increasing labor supply unlikely to increase employment, hiring credits maximally effective • Usual distributional arguments weaker in present context
How to increasing short-run impact of hiring credits • Target broadly, to avoid substitution away from other workers (and stigma) • Keep burden low by using simple rule—like rising employment—that we can live with in current context • Make credits short-term and temporary, to counter business cycle • No reason to focus on small firms (like California’s NJC) • Avoid retroactive credits, to induce new hiring • Create incentives for growth in employmentnot hours (more important, and margin on which supply is more responsive) • Don’t expand eligibility, letting credit become general tax relief
Hard to estimate costs of job creation via hiring credits, but much cheaper than ARRA • Windfall rate high, likely over 90% • Benefits are both direct (lower UI) and indirect (higher earnings through increased skills) • Estimates of cost/job from hiring credits fairly high, $9,100-$75,000 • At midpoint of range, about 1/7th of cost/job created via ARRA (CBO: 1.4-3.6 million jobs at $570 billion through Sept. 2010) • $290,000 at midpoint, vs. $42,000 for hiring credits
Limited scope of hiring credits at state level, but keep focus on job creation • “Feasible” state spending would have modest impact • E.g., suppose California spend $1 billion • Implication is about 24,000 more jobs (using cost midpoint), or unemployment lower by about .15 percentage point • Even low estimate of cost/job ($9,100) would imply only 110,000 jobs, unemployment rate lower by 0.6 percentage point • Federal government has far greater resources, and can borrow huge amounts • ARRA, distributed by population, would represent $68 billion of spending in California • Still, state hiring credits likely more effective than menu of proposals put forth by legislators
Basis for federal stimulus II? • Focusing new federal stimulus on hiring credits only could give similar impact for much smaller price tag • $50 billion would create 1.2 million jobs, vs. 1.4-3.6 million estimate of job creation by ARRA (CBO) • Might think policy could get bipartisan support, given focus on helping economy recover by reducing costs to businesses
Different sized ideas • Emphasize hiring credits for short-term response to Great Recession • Target unemployed broadly, keep it simple, and focus on job growth • Prepare better for future recessions • Establish new federal hiring credit that kicks in when economy slows, fade out when economy recovers • Avoids entanglement with politics, and budgetary difficulties that accompany recessions • Acts as “automatic stabilizer”