380 likes | 388 Views
This class discusses pricing strategies for firms with market power, including standard pricing and profits, and explores first, second, and third-degree price discrimination. Learn how to maximize profits and implement different pricing strategies. Don't forget to attend the review session tonight at 7PM!
E N D
Welcome to EC 209: Managerial Economics- Group ABy:Dr. Jacqueline Khorassani Week Twelve
Managerial Economics- Group A Week Twelve- Class 1 Monday, November 19 11:10-12:00Fottrell (AM) Aplia Asst Due tomorrow before 5 PM Don’t forget Review Session 7PM Tonight O'Flaherty Theatre
Chapter 11 Pricing Strategies for Firms with Market Power
Standard Pricing and Profits for Firms with Market Power Price Profits from standard pricing = Q * (P – AC) = $8 10 If C(Q) = 2Q Then MC = 2 Remember If P = 10-2Q R = PQ = 10Q -2Q2 MR = 10-4Q 8 6 4 To max profits MC = MR 2 = 10-4Q Q = 2 MC=AC 2 P = 10 - 2Q 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity MR = 10 - 4Q Plug Q = 2 into your demand equation P = 10- 2 (2) P = 6
Marginal Revenue and Elasticity • Recall own price elasticity of demand E = %Δ Q / %ΔP Where %Δ Q= dQ/Q %ΔP = dP/P E= dQ/Q divided by dP/P E = (dQ/dP) * P/Q
Also revenue is R = P.Q • Where P is a function of Q • so R(Q) = P(Q).Q • dR/dQ = dR/dP . dP/dQ + dR/dQ . dQ/dQ • dR/dQ = Q * dP/dQ + P * 1 • MR = P (Q/P . dP/dQ + 1) • We know that (dQ/dP) * P/Q = E • MR = P ( 1/E + 1) • MR = P(E + 1)/E
MR = P(E + 1)/E • If E = -1 MR = 0 • If E is a smaller negative number MR <0 • If E is a bigger negative number MR> 0 • Note: A firm will never produce a level where MR < 0.
A Simple Markup Rule • Suppose the elasticity of demand for the firm’s product is EF. • Since MR = P[1 + EF]/ EF • Setting MR = MC • P[1 + EF]/ EF = MC • P = [EF/(1+ EF)] MC • P = K x MC where K is the markup factor • The optimal price is a simple markup over relevant costs!
Mark-up Factor= EF/(1+ EF) • If EF = -2 • Then Mark-up factor = -2/ -1 • Price is 2 times MC • If EF = -4 • Then Mark-up factor = -4/ -3 • Price is 4/3 of MC • The more elastic the demand, the lower the markup.
Markup Rule for Cournot Oligopoly • Homogeneous product Cournot oligopoly. • N = total number of firms in the industry. • Market elasticity of demand EM . • Elasticity of individual firm’s demand is given by EF = N x EM. • Since P = [EF/(1+ EF)] MC, • Then, P = [NEM/(1+ NEM)] MC. • The greater the number of firmsthe lower the profit-maximizing markup factor.
An Example • Homogeneous product Cournot industry, 3 firms. • MC = $10. • Elasticity of market demand = - ½. • Determine the profit-maximizing price? • EF = NEM = 3 (-1/2) = -1.5. • P = [NEM/(1+ NEM)] MC. • P = [-1.5/(1- 1.5] $10. • P = 3 $10 = $30.
First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimination • Practice of charging each consumer the maximum amount he or she will pay for each incremental unit. • Permits a firm to extract all surplus from consumers.
Perfect Price Discrimination Price Profits*: .5(4-0)(10 - 2) = $16 10 In practice, transactions costs and information constraints make this difficult to implement perfectly. Price discrimination won’t work if consumers can resell the good. 8 6 Total Cost* =$8 4 2 MC = AC D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity
Second-Degree Price Discrimination Part of Consumer surplus is captured by the firm Price • The practice of posting a discrete schedule of declining prices for different quantities. • Eliminates the information constraint present in first-degree price discrimination. • Example: Electric utilities MC $10 $8 $5 D 2 4 Quantity The first 2 units are sold at $8/unit The second 2 units are sold at $5/unit
Managerial Economics- Group A • Week Twelve- Class 2 • Tuesday, November 20 • Cairnes • 15:10-16:00 • Aplia assignment is due before 5PM today • Send me questions on the entire course material
Last Class we talked about two types of price discrimination • First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimination • charging each consumer the maximum amount he or she will pay for each incremental unit. • Firm captures the entire Consumer Surplus • Hard to implement • Second-Degree Price Discrimination • posting a discrete schedule of declining prices for different quantities. • Does not capture the entire Consumer Surplus • Easier to implement
Third-Degree Price Discrimination • charging different groups of consumers different prices for the same product. • Group must have observable characteristics for third-degree price discrimination to work. • Examples • student discounts, • senior citizen’s discounts, • regional & international pricing.
Implementing Third-Degree Price Discrimination • Demands by two groups have different elasticities, E1 < E2. • Notice that group 2 is more price sensitive than group 1. • Who should be paying a lower price? • Group 2 • Profit-maximizing prices? • P1 = [E1/(1+ E1)] MC • P2 = [E2/(1+ E2)] MC
An Example • Suppose the elasticity of demand for Kodak film in the US is EU = -1.5, and the elasticity of demand in Japan is EJ = -2.5. • Marginal cost of manufacturing film is $3. • PU = [EU/(1+ EU)] MC = [-1.5/(1 - 1.5)] $3 = $9 • PJ = [EJ/(1+ EJ)] MC = [-2.5/(1 - 2.5)] $3 = $5 • Kodak’s optimal third-degree pricing strategy is to charge a higher price in the US, where demand is less elastic.
Two-Part Pricing • If it isn’t feasible to charge different prices for different units sold, • but demand information is known, • two-part pricing may permit you to extract all surplus from consumers. • Two-part pricing consists of a fixed fee and a per unit charge. • Example: • Athletic club memberships. • You may pay a monthly membership fee • Plus a small fee for each visit
Example • An average (typical) consumer’s demand is P = 10 – 2Q & MC = 2 • Set P = MC = 2 • Find Q • 10 - 2Q = 2 Q = 4 • Find Consumer surplus
To find Consumer Surplus Price • Draw the demand curve P = 10 -2 Q • Draw the MC curve • Intersection gives you the price 10 8 6 Fixed Fee = consumer surplus = Profits = €16 Per Unit Charge 4 MC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity
Block Pricing • packaging multiple units of an identical product together and selling them as one package. • Examples • Paper towels. • Six-packs of soda.
An Algebraic Example • Typical consumer’s demand is P = 10 - 2Q • C(Q) = 2Q • Optimal number of units in a package? • Optimal package price?
To determine the optimal quantity per package Price • Find Q from P = MC • MC = 2 • P= 10 - 2Q • 2= 10-2Q • Q = 4 10 8 6 4 MC = AC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity
To find the optimal price for the Package Price Consumer’s valuation of 4 units = .5(8)(4) + (2)(4) = $24 Therefore, set P = $24! Find out the value of 4 units to consumer & set a price equal to that The value to consumer is the area under the demand curve 10 8 6 4 MC = AC 2 D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity
Costs and Profits with Block Pricing Price 10 Profits = [.5(8)(4) + (2)(4)] – (2)(4) = $16 8 6 4 Costs = (2)(4) = $8 2 MC = AC D 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity
Commodity Bundling • The practice of bundling two or more products together and charging one price for the bundle. • Examples • Holiday packages. • Computers and software. • Film and developing.
MC PH DH PL MRH DL MRL QL QH Peak-Load Pricing Price • demand during peak times is higher than the capacity of the firm • the firm engages in peak-load pricing. • Charge a higher price (PH) during peak times (DH). • Charge a lower price (PL) during off-peak times (DL). Quantity
Cross-Subsidies • Prices charged for one product are subsidized by the sale of another product. • May be profitable when there are significant demand complementarities effects. • Examples • Browser and server software. • Drinks and meals at restaurants.
Double Marginalization • Example • A large firm has division • the upstream division is the sole provider of a key input. • the downstream division uses the input produced by the upstream division to produce the final output. • Incentives to maximize divisional profits leads the upstream manager to produce where MRU = MCU. • Implication: PU > MCU.
Double Marginalization • Similarly the downstream division has market power and has an incentive to maximize divisional profits, the manager will produce where MRD = MCD. • Implication: PD > MCD. • Thus, both divisions mark price up over marginal cost resulting in a phenomenon called double marginalization. • Result: less than optimal overall profits for the firm.
Managerial Economics- Group A • Week Twelve- Class 3 • Thursday, November 22 • 15:10-16:00 • Tyndall • Next Aplia Assignment is due before 5 PM on Tuesday, November 27
Last time we talked about • Double marginalization • What doe it mean? • The manager of the pasta factory that belongs to the restaurant and only provides pastas to the restaurant • And the manager of the restaurant • Maximizing their profits separately • Not the best strategy
Instead the firm should maximize the overall profits of selling the final good (product of the restaurant) • This is called “Transfer Pricing” • That is MRr = MCr + MCp where MRr is marginal revenue of restaurant MCr is marginal cost of restaurant MCp is marginal cost of pasta factory MRr - MCr = MCp NMRr = MCp • The pasta factory produces such that its marginal cost equals the net marginal revenue of restaurant (NMRr)
Pricing in Markets with Intense Price Competition • Price Matching • Advertising a price and a promise to match any lower price offered by a competitor. • No firm has an incentive to lower their prices. • Each firm charges the monopoly price and shares the market.
Pricing in Markets with Intense Price Competition • Randomized Pricing • A strategy of constantly changing prices. • Decreases consumers’ incentive to shop around as they cannot learn from experience which firm charges the lowest price. • Reduces the ability of rival firms to undercut a firm’s prices
Other information • Posted three sample MCQ on my website & on blackboard as well • Also, remember to check blackboard for sample of previous years’ exams • There is going to be another Review Session on Wednesday, November 28 at 7-9 pm in IT250 1st floor • Send me your questions • I will post the answers on my website.