350 likes | 384 Views
Local Public Finance. Chapter 16 (All Economics is Local). Collective Choice. Median voter model Majority rule: median person’s preferences win How to influence median voter? Decide who has standing in the decision Facilitate “your side” to vote. Evaluating Social Utility.
E N D
Local Public Finance Chapter 16 (All Economics is Local) 1
Collective Choice • Median voter model • Majority rule: median person’s preferences win • How to influence median voter? • Decide who has standing in the decision • Facilitate “your side” to vote. 2
Evaluating Social Utility • Pareto optimal improvement: at least one person gains and nobody is harmed from a change in policy. • Difficult to achieve in practice • Potential Pareto improvement: the “winner” is able to compensate the “loser” and still have surplus remaining. 3
Valuation techniques • Consumer surplus (Ch 6) • Ignores existence value • Willingness to pay • How much are you willing to pay to see a project through to its completion? • Implicitly assumes everyone has same income or at least same preferences (high-income people dictate social preferences) • Willingness to accept • How much will you need to be compensated be just as well off with the status quo? 4
Arrow’s Voting Paradox • Solution to philosophical quagmire: • Majority voting: • Everyone gets one vote independent of their income • Not flawless: Social choices of rational people may not be transitive, and may seem irrational. • Three Projects:α,β, and γ. αP β, β P γ a, and γ P α! (“P” means “preferred to”.) 5
Local public goods • Citizens can vote at ballot boxes or vote with their feet • Congestion—public goods are mostly club goods • Neither government nor private sector is always best at provision • Spillover effects • Some pay but do not benefit • Others benefit but do not pay 7
Assumptions of Tiebout Hypothesis • All residents can move costlessly; • Everyone has perfect knowledge about the qualities of each community; • Enough jurisdictions exist to provide a full range of public goods; • All communities, regardless of size, have the same cost functions for their services; • Public goods do not cause any positive or negative spillovers; and • There is no social discrimination by jurisdictions. 8
Public Finance Viewpoints • Traditional public finance theory • Government is benevolent, omniscient. • Government efficiently allocates resources to provide optimal quantities of public goods; • It redistributes income to create a more equitable and more just society; and • It is responsible for maintaining economic stability. Public officials select policies that maximize social welfare. 9
Public Finance Viewpoints • Public choice theory • Civil servants maximize their personal utility functions • They cannot maximize the “common good” because such a thing is neither definable nor measurable. • Maximization of social welfare results in the maximization of benefits to the most zealous lobbyists, interest groups and rent-seekers • Government will inevitably become excessively large, unaccountable and untrustworthy. 10
Provision of club goods • Market fails in efficiently providing club goods because of • externalities, • imperfect competition, • free-riders, • lack of precise information, • excessive regulation, • improper incentives to provide an adequate amount of the quasi-public good. 11
Provision of club goods • Government fails in efficiently providing club goods because of • Unreliable signals of the electors’ preferences • Arrow’s voting paradox • Rational ignorance (electors bear high costs of being well-informed; marginal benefit—their one vote) • Inertia inherent in bureaucracies, • Tendency to mandate quick fixes (and its associated “law of unintended consequences”), • Distributional inequalities. 12
Revenue Sources of Local Government • Benefit principle: Whoever benefits from a public program should pay • Difficult to determine with spillovers • Free-riders • Marginal cost of provision 0 • Ability to pay • Equity and equal sacrifice • Results in progressive taxes 13
Tax Incidence: Partial Equilibrium Analysis • Who bears the tax? • Excise tax: consumption tax paid when product is purchased. • When imposed, an excise tax shifts supply inward • Consumers see higher prices • Producers see lower per-unit revenues • Society worse-off by deadweight loss 14
Tax Incidence Partial Equilibrium Analysis • Whether consumers or producers bear the most part of the tax depends on the relative price elasticities of supply and demand 15
Tax Incidence: General Equilibrium Analysis • Quantity sold falls, fewer workers are needed, so excise taxes increase unemployment in: • the taxed industry (direct effect), • the industries that supply products that the tax industry needs (indirect effect), and • the industries that provide goods and services that the affected workers would use (induced effect.) 17
Laffer curve • High tax rates decrease revenues • Reduce incentives to work • Encourage consumption of leisure activities • Encourage participation in shadow (hidden) economy • Barter • Work for cash • Tax avoidance mechanisms • Encourage out-migration 18
Laffer curve 19
Optimal local tax policy • Traditional public finance theory • Government maximizes its tax revenue to allow provision of sufficient quantities of public goods. • Public choice theorists • Taxpayers exchange their money for an optimal amount of public goods. • Politicians choose the tax rates and fees to minimize their political cost function. • They respond to preferences of social income groups and interest groups. 20
Property taxes • Controversial tax • Equitable: Property values benefit from efficient provision of services and amenities. • Critics: • Property taxes have nothing to do with either the ability to pay or the benefits received • Homeowners on fixed incomes are hurt. • Property tax supports services that have an inverse relation to property values. 21
Incidence of property taxes:Three schools of thought • Traditional view • Property composed of land and buildings • One jurisdiction raises its tax rate • If supply of land fixed, portion of tax attributable to land falls on landowners • Portion of tax on buildings acts like excise tax • Households and firms flee to other jurisdictions • Property tax regressive 22
Incidence of property taxesThree schools of thought • New view (Mieszkowski) • Extends traditional view • What if all jurisdictions increase rates by the same amount? • Similar to national property tax—no migration 23
Incidence of property taxesThree schools of thought • New view (continued) • Taxes fall on all capital owners • Property owners would sell, decreasing the value of real property everywhere. • They would invest in assets not subject to property tax, like bonds. • Increase demand for bonds, bond prices rise • Inverse relation between bond prices and interest rates, so interest rates fall 24
Incidence of property taxesThree schools of thought • Benefit view (Hamilton) • Accounts for benefits and costs • Property tax is user charge. • Tiebout hypothesis • Value of services and value of tax are capitalized into property values. • If the amount of taxes equals the value of benefits, then the landowners both benefit from and pay for the local public goods. • Property tax is distributionally neutral 25
Municipal sales taxes • Essentially excise taxes • Some consumers purchase goods from outside the jurisdiction • Regressive (the poor spend a higher proportion of their incomes) • Exportable • May cause retail firms to relocate just outside jurisdictional boundaries (cause spatial mismatch?) 26
Local income taxes • Decrease the incentive to work • Increase propensity to migrate • Taxes on corporate income • Encourage firms to relocate • Firms act on after-tax income rather than pre-tax income 27
User Fees • Prices for local services • (Close to) Marginal cost pricing • Efficient for financing club goods with few externalities • Water provision • Sewerage • Garbage collection • Chimney sweeps (according to Norwegian study) 28
Tax Exporting • Interspatial incidence • Taxes in tourist areas borne by vacationers • Works very well if area lacks nearby alternatives (hotel room tax in Hawaii) 29
Appendix • Indifference curve analysis combines willingness and ability to determine quantity of two goods consumed by one individual • Edgeworth box • Assumes fixed amount of output of two goods • Analyzes optimal distribution of these two goods. • If production possibilities curve shifts, Edgeworth boxes change 30
Edgeworth box • Two goods, (grapes and carrots) • Two protagonists (Dick and Jane) • Original endowment • Dick: 15 carrots, 40 grapes • Jane: 60 carrots, 10 grapes 33
Edgeworth box • Pareto optimal redistribution: makes at least one person better off without decreasing the satisfaction of the other. • Contract curve • The contract curve locus of points where the two sets of indifference curves are tangent. • When a distribution ends up on the contract curve, no Pareto optimal redistribution exists 34
Edgeworth box • NOTE: the optimal distribution does not have to be in the middle of the box. • Preferences can also be corner solutions. • To be equitable, a distribution may not be equal. • Equity vs. equality • If we take subsequent production incentives into account, an equal distribution may affect the placement of production possibility curve during the next time period. 35