1 / 7

Anatomy of Intangible Transfer Pricing Scheme, With A Focus on Corporate Restruc

"Amidst the OECD's inclusionary efforts, many issues remain unresolved, particularly when it comes to the transfer of intangibles for the specific purpose of bus"<br>TaxGuru is a platform that provides Updates On Amendments in Income Tax, Wealth Tax, Company Law, Service Tax, RBI, Custom Duty, Corporate Lawu00a0, Goods and Service Tax etc.<br>To know more visit https://taxguru.in/income-tax/anatomy-intangible-transfer-pricing-scheme-focus-corporate-restructurings.html

taxguru
Download Presentation

Anatomy of Intangible Transfer Pricing Scheme, With A Focus on Corporate Restruc

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Anatomy of Intangible Transfer Pricing Scheme, With A Focus on Corporate Restructurings taxguru.in/income-tax/anatomy-intangible-transfer-pricing-scheme-focus-corporate-restructurings.html May 18, 2022 1. INTRODUCTION Intangible assets characterize an entire era of economic-related technological innovation. Many argue that intangibles have created the “New Economy,” or a global economy in which wealth is no longer integrated in tangible assets such as land, but instead in assets related to conceptual, reputational, and technical capital. Given the inherent difficulties in measuring, valuing, and allocating value in this category of assets, taxation issues are unavoidable. The issue is especially acute in the case of multinational enterprises (MNEs), where intangible assets are developed and converted internally among members of a group of companies. It is easily understandable why countries suffer significant revenue losses because of the deception of intangible assets, which is frequently part of MNE-created tax avoidance schemes. The OECD has tried to mitigate the effects of this issue by providing updated assistance in its Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) Project, particularly Actions 8-10[1] on transfer pricing and intangibles. Amidst the OECD’s inclusionary efforts, many issues remain unresolved, particularly when it comes to the transfer of intangibles for the specific purpose of business restructurings. Cross- border transfers of intangibles are frequently made with the final goal of changing corporate structures, such as when a company is entirely comprised of this type of assets (IP company). Corporations carefully plan these transfers as section of their tax planning strategies, and they have significant ramifications for global taxation and the economy. 2. INTANGIBLES 2.1 Definition 1/7

  2. The OECD defines intangible as “something that is not a physical asset or a financial asset, that is “capable of being owned or controlled for use in commercial activities, and whose use or transfer would be compensated had it occurred in a transaction between independent parties in comparable circumstances”[2] in Actions 8-10 of the BEPS project. Patents, trade secrets, trademarks, licenses, goodwill and ongoing concern value, and some market particularities are examples of intangible assets, according to the OECD definition. It must be acknowledged that, in addition to intangible assets themselves, rights in intangible assets can be transferred between corporations. 3. TAXATION ISSUES RELATING TO INTANGIBLE ASSETS When trying to discuss the impact on the economy of intangible assets, one important factor to consider is the taxation of these kind of assets. The distinctiveness of intangibles, and thus the unlikelihood of assessing them, is the beginning point for taxing them. To identify the estimated price of intangibles, the least risky solution is to determine similar assets or “comparable” assets.[3] This assumes a dependence on market rates where comparable transactions could be found, which is frequently insufficient. Aside from this broad aggravation, there are concerns in the domain of taxation. The first is if the cost of developing an intangible asset must be allowed to deduct from the year of formation or depreciated over many years equivalent to the asset’s average lifespan. The next issue would be whether intangibles have a restricted expected useful life and therefore should be depreciated, in the context that ideologies and intellectual property do not deteriorate in the same way that tangible assets do. The latter concern has been addressed by academia[4] and practise, as there is widespread agreement that intangible assets are depreciable[5]. Furthermore, intellectual property-related products such as patents and licences are only available for a limited period (i.e. 20 years for patents). Ultimately, the transfer pricing issue is the most pressing and persistent issue in the taxation of intangible assets. Provided that several multinational corporations use the transfer of intangible assets among group members to reduce their tax liabilities, either lawfully (tax avoidance) or unlawfully (tax evasion), the crucial question is just how we classify the transfer prices of intangible assets, particularly in cases where comparable transactions are lacking. 4. TRANSFER PRICING OF INTANGIBLES IN CASES OF COMPANY RESTRUCTURINGS To lay the groundwork for the problem of corporate restructurings, it was essential to analyze transfer pricing methods on intangible assets. I’ll try to explain the fundamentals of transfer pricing in corporate restructurings and how they connect to intangible assets. 4.1 Transfer Pricing in Company Restructurings As part of the BEPS Project implementation, the OECD publicly released specific guidelines on transfer pricing in cases of corporate restructurings[6] in the summer of 2016. The OECD’s definition of corporate restructuring serves as the foundation for this evaluation. A corporate restructuring is a cross-border rearrangement of commercial or 2/7

  3. financial connections among associated enterprises, which includes the dismissal or significant negotiations of existing arrangements. This definition’s cross-border component makes it obvious that transfer pricing is a consistent risk in these structures, which is correct. The depicted picture will be incomplete only if we clarify on the incentive schemes for companies to engage in corporate restructurings. In broad sense, there is a need for special purpose goods and services, economies of scale and scope, cost cutting, and the results appeared by synergies are encouraging businesses to restructure. [7] Diversification advantages are also essential when looking to disintegrate different risks across multiple jurisdictions.[8] These days, it is not uncommon to come across situations in which companies merge with the primary goal of combining knowledge or know-how. When intangibles are engaged, the main goal is to consolidate them by reallocating the risks and profits associated with these assets between persons of the MNE group. In accordance with prior guidelines, the OECD insists on the implementation of the arm’s length principle in corporate restructurings. Even though it acknowledges that MNEs participate in transactions which are not found in transactions among enterprises, it helps clarify that the absence of comparable doesn’t really render the ALP extremely difficult or useless.[9] As a result, to define the arm’s length price, we must first distinguish the happening transactions using a functional analysis. The assets involved in the restructuring, their economic significance, and the risks transferred and allocated will all be considered in this analysis. It will typically include a comparison of pre-restructuring conditions to post-restructuring conditions to identify all assets and risks converted. As a result, while the OECD’s logic is understandable, countries and authorities must be given more specific guidance. Thus, assessing commercial rationality is insufficient; we must also consider the conditions for each member individually, particularly the anticipated returns and the availability of possibilities for the transaction.[10] 5. CONCLUSION Intangible assets are a highly specialized field in transfer pricing that necessitates specialized knowledge as well as an understanding of wider matters. This paper demonstrates that even conventional transfer pricing techniques are commonly insufficient to face these challenges of intangibles. When intangibles are shifted as part of corporate restructurings, the picture becomes much hazier because the incentives for incorporating businesses must also be considered. In these circumstances, achieving a balance among fairness, free market function, and good health tax competition appears incredibly difficult. The arm’s length principle, according to the winter’s opinion, somehow doesn’t offer an effective solution to the issue of intangibles for several reasons. So, it seems that MNEs are organized this way to take full advantage of inter-company transactions, particularly intangibles, and the second is that intangibles transactions cannot adhere to the arm’s length principle due to a lack of comparable transactions if they exist at all. Another issue would be that judges fail to reach the intangibles problem appropriately and considerately, resulting in decision making that articulate outdated viewpoints. Therefore, in this way, they not only disallow smaller businesses from 3/7

  4. investing in intangible assets, but they also encourage MNEs to continue engaging in tax evasion and avoidance, resulting in massive revenue losses. As a result, the interaction of these factors has policy recommendations for all countries. An advanced version of the formulary apportionment method with special regulations for only certain types of intangible assets could as of now provide a workable solution to the intangibles problem in conjunction with corporate restructurings. A plethora of transfer pricing cases could be detected and resolved using formulary apportionment, which the OECD must also develop, resulting to stricter adherence and greater profits for certain countries. Concurrently, money invested in intangible assets will increase because companies will face decent tax burdens that will be dispersed across different jurisdictions. In the end, this would result in increased earnings in more countries, boosting the connection for international taxation and competition. Overall, the implementation of a formulary apportionment system will just stand to gain the international tax system overall, as well as individual countries. This strategy is not without risks and disadvantages, but if necessary, modifications are needed, intangible assets will give rise to even more significant growth, since intangible assets are the game changer of the modern economy. As noted, attorney Lloyd Cutler stated in 2000: “given that no company can establish a monopoly on brains, how do you keep the people that make it work? There are no tangible assets to divest. There is intellectual property and that’s about it- and a building.” [1] OECD ‘Aligning Transfer Pricing Outcomes with Value Creation, Action 8-10-2015 Final Reports’ (OECD Publishing, Paris 2015) [2] OECD (n 2) 67 [3] Blair and Wallman (n 1) 15 [4] Jason Cummins, ‘A New Approach to the valuation of Intangible Capital’ in Carlo Corrado, John Haltiwanger and Daniel Sichel (eds) Measuring Capital in the New Economy (The University of Chicago Press 2005) [5] Elisebeth landes and Andrew Rosenfeld, ‘The durability of advertising revisited’ (1994) 42 JIE 263. [6] OECD, ‘Conforming Amendments to Chapter IX of the Transfer Pricing Guidelines: Transfer Pricing aspects of Business Restructurings’ (OECD Publishing, Paris, 4 July 2016) [7] OECD (n 58) 9 [8] Caves (n 56) 2 [9] OECD (n 58) 11 [10] OECD (n 41) 379 Tags: OECD, Transfer Pricing 4/7

  5. Kindly Refer to Privacy Policy & Complete Terms of Use and Disclaimer. Author Bio Name: Chitrapu Anand Hitesh Qualification: Post Graduate Company: N/A Location: hyderabad, Telangana, India Member Since: 17 May 2022 | Total Posts: 1 View Full Profile Join Taxguru’s Network for Latest updates on Income Tax, GST, Company Law, Corporate Laws and other related subjects. Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp 5/7

  6. GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Whatsapp GROUP LINK Join us on Telegram GROUP LINK Review us on Google More Under Income Tax « Previous Article Next Article » 6/7

  7. Leave a Comment Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked * 7/7

More Related