330 likes | 453 Views
Distributional Impacts of Congestion Pricing. Douglass B. Lee, Jr. International Symposium on Road Pricing Key Biscayne, FL November 2003. Purpose. Efficiency versus Equity Equity horizontal vertical Objective Measurement (vs. eye of beholder) direct impact (as a tax)
E N D
Distributional Impacts of Congestion Pricing Douglass B. Lee, Jr. International Symposium on Road Pricing Key Biscayne, FL November 2003 US DOT/Volpe Center
Purpose • Efficiency versus Equity • Equity • horizontal • vertical • Objective Measurement (vs. eye of beholder) • direct impact (as a tax) • relative to current financing methods (recycling) • after behavioral response (incidence) US DOT/Volpe Center
Two Major Dimensions of Equity • Horizontal • treat equals equally • Vertical • impact on the distribution of income: reduce disparity (progressive), increase disparity (regressive), or neutral • impact on income class proportional to income is neutral • not everything is regressive US DOT/Volpe Center
Conclusions • Vertical equity impacts of peak pricing are not bad, not enough to be an obstacle to efficiency • true before revenue recycling; revenues can easily correct equity impacts (and also kill efficiency gains) • Alternative instruments are also not that bad, e.g., gasoline excise tax, property tax • Earmarking may be politically useful but is economically dubious if revenues are fungible (e.g., gambling revenues for education) US DOT/Volpe Center
1. Direct Impact • Definition of income • household, family, consumer unit, per capita • money, earned income, before tax, after transfers, permanent income, wealth • Method of Measurement • tax returns • expenditures • self-reported (c. 15% no response for NPTS) • categories, quantiles, density function US DOT/Volpe Center
Example Raw Income Data US DOT/Volpe Center
1999 Household Income source: 2000 Current Population Survey, Census Bureau US DOT/Volpe Center
NPTS 1995 US DOT/Volpe Center
Shares of Income by Decile US DOT/Volpe Center
Peak Congested Trips • Selected NPTS trips • mode = auto, SUV, van, or pickup • start time = 6:30 to 9:30 AM or 3:30 to 7:00 PM • travel day = weekday • place = urban, suburban, or second city (not town or rural or undetermined) • n= 52,000 out of 409,000 trips • Ignores • peak direction • trip length • degree of congestion (demand vs. capacity) • occupancy US DOT/Volpe Center
Tax on Peak Trips • Each trip charged a fixed amount • same amount (“toll”) for each trip • “Tax” is borne entirely by any person currently driving in the peak • whether they stay or change is not considered (yet) US DOT/Volpe Center
Distribution of Peak Trips US DOT/Volpe Center
Peak Trips versus Income US DOT/Volpe Center
Distributional Analysis • Restate impact of policy as a percent of income for each income class • Horizontal line is neutral; falling (tax) is regressive US DOT/Volpe Center
Peak Trips as Percent of Income US DOT/Volpe Center
Observations • Tax impact generally rises with income, but not as rapidly • A tax per trip on existing peak travelers is mildly regressive, according to these data • Data are noisy, and noise tends to flatten the distribution (i.e., toward random) • Permanent income reduces regressiveness US DOT/Volpe Center
Shares of SR-91 Users by Income Group US DOT/Volpe Center
Histogram of SR-91 Users by Income US DOT/Volpe Center
Histogram with Fitted Density Function US DOT/Volpe Center
Distribution Fitted to 1999 Household Income US DOT/Volpe Center
Relative Burden Function US DOT/Volpe Center
Direct Burden for SR-91 US DOT/Volpe Center
2. Recycling of Revenues • Fuel excise tax, general sales tax, local property tax reduction • Consumption of gasoline and oil as percent of income/expenditures • excise tax is proportional to gallons, not to dollar amount paid (i.e., not a sales tax) • Compare revenue-neutral policies US DOT/Volpe Center
Distribution of Gas/Oil Expense US DOT/Volpe Center
Gas and Oil Expenditures by Decile US DOT/Volpe Center
Gasoline Expenditures as % of Income US DOT/Volpe Center
Comparison of Two Taxes US DOT/Volpe Center
3. Shifting and Incidence • Individuals who change behavior reduce the burden of the tax/toll on themselves; those who stay and pay bear the full brunt • More careful analysis has been done for national tax instruments, but not for congestion tolls or “value pricing” • Behavioral responses can be estimated, but data are very few US DOT/Volpe Center
Shifting the Burden • If employers pay commuting, burden is shifted to owners and customers • If costs are tax deductible, burden is diffused among taxpayers • Behavior changes to avoid the tax/toll cause some redistribution of the burden • Not zero-sum; delay is “deadweight” loss • e.g., tax on luxury (>100 feet) yachts US DOT/Volpe Center
Supply-Demand Elasticities US DOT/Volpe Center
Behavior Changes • No change • high time-value travelers may prefer time savings with toll • Shift route • increases time for traveler, impacts travelers on parallel routes • Shift to carpool or transit • may leave traveler better off (cost plus time), impacts other modes • Shift time • traveler worse off than before but less than paying the toll • Shift locations • workplace or residence or other destination US DOT/Volpe Center
Correcting Vertical Equity Impacts • Use of revenues from congestion pricing (Small rule) • reduce general taxes or other user fees • improve attractiveness of alternative transportation modes • redistribute revenues according to income (low income receives largest compensation) US DOT/Volpe Center