540 likes | 708 Views
Auditing Section Doctoral Consortium January 2006. Jere R. Francis Curators’ Professor KPMG Research Professor University of Missouri, USA francis@missouri.edu. Data Innovation in Empirical Audit Research. Do what you enjoy, and find the right data for the RQ Innovation through new data
E N D
Auditing SectionDoctoral ConsortiumJanuary 2006 Jere R. FrancisCurators’ Professor KPMG Research Professor University of Missouri, USAfrancis@missouri.edu
Data Innovation in Empirical Audit Research • Do what you enjoy, and find the right data for the RQ • Innovation through new data • Use new data to answer “old” questions better or to answer “new” questions that could not previously be investigated • public data – new U.S. audit fee data or internal control reports • but risky because of competition • private data avoids competition • but can be risky because it’s costly and the outcome is unknown • Novel use of existing public data • Creatively use existing data in new ways • link financial statement properties (e.g., abnormal accruals) with auditor characteristics • Becker et al. (CAR 1998) & Francis et al. (AJPT 1999) • office-level analysis of Big 4 accounting firms • Reynolds &Francis (JAE 2000)
Audit Research:Intersection of practice, theory & research design choices • Practice drives research questions (RQ) • Some examples (next slides) • Theory informs/frames RQ • Economics, agency & signaling theory, psychology • Research design – many choices • Modeling, experimental, & archival • Inherent limits of RQs answerable by a single approach/method • Value of triangulation/complementarity
Examples of Practice-Driven Empirical Audit Research • 1970s – Congressional investigations • Allegations of large-firm cartel pricing & predatory pricing • Motivated first studies of audit pricing • 1980s – effects of deregulation • Allegations of low-balling and poor audit quality • Motivated studies of initial engagement pricing • 1990s – legal liability and audit litigation crisis (S&L, PSLRA) • Motivated risk-screening studies, & effects of PSLRA • 1990s – growth of industry specialization and non-audit services • Motivated study of industry expertise and non-audit services • 2000s – New regulations/institutions • The effects of PCAOB and SOX on audit practice/quality
Triangulation - Low Balling • Theory -modeling pricing incentives & consequences on auditor independence • DeAngelo JAE 1981; Dye JAE 1991 • Experimental evidence • Economics – induce LB in the lab & effects on audit quality • Schatzburg (TAR 1990); Schatzburg & Sevcik (CAR 1994); Dopuch & King (JAAF 1996) • Psychology – effects of “fee pressure” on the quality of auditor judgments • Houston (AJPT 1999) • Empirical evidence • Initial engagement discounts • Simon & Francis (TAR 1988); Craswell & Francis (TAR 1999) • Consequences of LB on audit hours/audit quality • Deis and Giroux (JAPP 1996), sample of school district audits
Units of Analysis in Audit Research(“red” denotes prime empirical areas) • Audit testing & evidence-gathering procedures • Auditor judgments about testing & evidence • Auditors apply/interpret testing procedures • As individuals (individual judgments) • In teams (group judgments) • Accounting firms • Auditors work in firms • Observable “audit firm” outcomes are audit reports & audited financial statements (and who audits whom) • Audit industry and audit markets • Audit firms operate & compete in audit markets • Regulatory institutions and public policy • Auditors, firms and markets are regulated
Audit Testing Procedures(requires accounting firms) • Purpose • Understanding, evaluating and improving the quality of audit testing and evidence-gathering procedures • Historical examples • Are accounts receivable confirmations effective/reliable? • Caster (AJPT 1990) • Is classical sampling efficient/effective in auditing? • Lead to development of dollar-unit sampling • Current examples • Archival - Do control risk assessments affect other audit tests? • Mock and Wright (AJPT 1999), test of the “audit risk model” • Experimental - Is the new “business risk” audit approach effective? • O’Donnell & Schultz (TAR 2005)
Auditor Judgment Research • Purpose • To understand how auditors implement tests, interpret evidence • Ultimate goal – to improve audit judgments in the field • Historical examples • Descriptive models (1970s) • What information cues affect auditor decision-making? • Heuristics and biases (1980s) • Are auditors different than other decision-makers? • Memory and cognition (1990s) • What do auditors know and why? • Some current examples • Do different “interventions” affect auditor-client negotiation outcomes? • Do alternative forms of “review” affect auditor performance? • Do “groups” outperform individuals? • Audit teams required to “brainstorm” for fraud risk • Does the “business risk” model improve auditor judgments?
Accounting Firms(proprietary & largely a black box) • Purpose • Understanding the organization and administrative structures of accounting firms • Field studies – e.g., Dirsmith & Covaleski (AOS 1985) • Examples of RQ • How centralized/decentralized are firms? • How much autonomy do local offices/partners have? • A central issue in Andersen’s Enron audit • How do partners share profits? What are incentive effects? • Large vs. small profit-sharing pools, and awarding of partnership units • Burrows & Black (AOS 1998); Trompeter (AJPT 1994); Liu & Simunic (TAR 2005) • Do firm reputations (audit quality) vary? • Across offices? Across countries? If so, why? • Begs the question of what is an accounting firm? More on this later
Observable Audit Outcomes • Direct (who audits whom?) • Auditor resignations/client disagreements (8-Ks) • Krishnan & Krishnan (TAR 1997); Shu (JAE 2000) • Audit reports • Are reports informative? GC and New I/C reports • Indirect • Financial statement/earnings quality • Jointly produced by companies/auditors • Work to date is limited mainly to “accruals” • Secondary effects of differential audit quality • Debt markets • Mansi et al. (JAR 2004) • Equity markets • Khurana et al. (TAR 2004); Teoh & Wong (TAR 1993)
Examples of audit-outcome research questions • How do auditor characteristics affect audit outcomes? • Firm size, brand name, industry expertise • Locale/unit of analysis (global, country, office, partner) • How do engagement-specific characteristics affect audit outcomes? • Proxies for independence • Fees (client influence), engagement tenure, auditor alumni, • How do client characteristics affect audit outcomes? • Corporate governance (e.g., audit committees) • How do institutions affect audit outcomes? • Regulatory agencies, litigation & investor protection
Audit Industry & Markets • Industry Structure • Why is the industry dominated by large firms? • Scale economies? • Yes – Banker et al. (JAE 2003) • No – Zind & Zeghal (CAR 1991) • Positive spillovers in joint production of audit/other services? • Economies of scope? • Simunic (JAR 1984); Whisenant et al. (JAR 2003) • Audit Market Structure • Are audit markets competitive, or monopolistic? • Oligopoly/monopolistic competition? • Is there demand for (supply of) differential audit quality? • If so, why? How is it priced? How is audit quality affected? • How have mergers/consolidations affected audit markets?
Regulatory Institutions • How do professional bodies & regulatory institutions affect audits and accounting firms? • Examples of RQ: • How do sanctions affect audits/firms? • Wilson & Grimlund (APJT 1990) – SEC’s AAER • Hilary and Lennox (JAE 2006) – POB Peer Reviews • How do legal liability regimes affect audits? • Analytical/Experimental • Dye (JPE 1993; JAE 1997); Dopuch et al. (JAE 1997) • Empirical • Francis & Krishnan (APJAE 2003); Lee & Mande (AJPT 2003); • Current topics • How do current regulations (PCAOB/SOX) affect audits? • Should nonaudit services (including taxes) be banned?
Empirical Research on Audit Quality Audits are relatively cheap, and proven failures are infrequent. But this does not necessarily mean audits are always of high quality. What do we know about audit quality from empirical research?
Research on Audit Outcomes What do know about audit quality from audit report research?
Inferring Audit Quality from Audit Reports • After 1989, only two primary audit reports • Standard clean opinion (90%) • Modified opinion for going concern (GC) (10%) • How do users respond to “modified” reports? • Are modified reports perceived to convey “negative” news? • If so, then audit reports are informative and auditing has value to users
Type 1 & 2 Error Rates(1995-2003 Compustat Population) • Clean opinions (90%), GC (10%), n= 62,094 firm-year observations • Overall Error Rate – 9.5% • Type 1 Errors (false negatives) – 9% (over-qualifying or auditor conservatism) • No bankruptcy within one year, but 9% had GC reports • 5,467 GC reports for 785 bankruptcies (7 GC per bankruptcy) • Type 2 Errors (false positives) – 55% (under-qualifying) • Bankruptcy within one year (785) but no GC 55% of time, i.e., 432 cases over an 8-year period
Do Modified Audit Reports Matter(given type 1/2 errors?) • Informational value is difficult to assess • Audit reports issued concurrently with financials • Most GC reports are “repeat offenders” • Evidence that “surprise” first-time GC reports reduce share prices • Dodd et al. (JAE 1984), Loudder et al. (AJPT 1992) • Predictive ability of modified audit reports for material loss contingences (lawsuits) • Raghundan (CAR 1993)
Audit Reports and the IPO Setting • Audit report has potentially more value • Greater information uncertainty/asymmetry • Weber and Willenborg (JAR 2003) • Microcap IPO’s < $10 million • 23% have GC reports preceding IPO • Pre-IPO audit reports predict delistings and future stock returns • But more so for large (Big 4 & national) auditors
Who Audits Whom? What do we know about auditor differences and audit quality?
Differential Audit Quality Research • Audit quality cannot be directly observed • Except for “proven” audit failures (ex post) which are rare • Instead – differential audit quality is inferred • Comparing audit outcomes between “classes” of auditors • All firms are assumed to meet minimum professional & legal requirements • But many different types of firms exist • Suggests supply of differential auditing • Implies differential demand (clienteles)
Audit Firm Size:Is Bigger Better? • The big firm/small firm dichotomy • Big 8 (now Big 4) firms have brand name reputation and incentives to protect their reputation • Simunic and Stein (1987 CGA Monograph) • Auditor size proxies for quality due to less fee dependence (DeAngelo, JAE 1981) • Client dependence = 1/n (where n=number of clients) • Now we can use actual fee dependence • Doesn’t mean Big 4 audits are always better • It just means that on average they are better • Individual audit failures can and do occur
Evidence of Big 4 Audit Quality Differentiation • Audit pricing • Big 4 audit fee premia of 20-50% • US, Australia, Hong Kong, UK • Implies more quantity and/or better quality auditing • Higher fees imply voluntary demand for higher quality audits by some clients • Demand for quality • Demand for Big 4 audits is increasing in agency costs • Francis & Wilson (TAR 1988), DeFond (AJPT 1992) • IPOs with larger auditors have less IPO underpricing • Beatty (TAR 1989), Willenborg (JAR 1999)
Other Evidence • Big accounting firms are sued less often • Litigation as quality proxy (Palmose, TAR, 1987) • Big firms sanctioned less often by regulators • Feroz et al. (JAR 1991) • Alternative explanation is that big firms are more powerful and have resources to fight • But evidence on audit “outcomes” is more consistent with higher quality • Let’s turn to that evidence
Evidence from Audit Outcomes • Audit Reports of Large (Big 4) Auditors • More conservative reports (more modifications) • Francis & Krishnan (CAR 1999), (APJAE 2003) • More informative reports (predictive power) • IPO setting, Weber & Willenborg (JAR 2003) • More accurate reports in UK, Lennox (ABR 1999) • Financial Statements Audited by Big 4 Auditors • Smaller abnormal accruals -- less managerial discretion • Becker et al. (CAR 1998), Francis et al. (AJPT 1999) • Accruals/earnings surprises valued higher in the stock market • Teoh & Wong (TAR 1993), Krishnan (AJPT 2003)
Conclusions on Auditor Size • Evidence is supportive of higher Big 4 audit quality • But an alternative explanation is endogeneity • i.e., “good” companies choose good (Big 4) auditors, in which case selection may explain outcomes, not audit quality • Heckman 2-stage approach is trendy • But most studies using it support prior findings on audit quality • Weber & Willenborg (JAR 2003), Hogan (TAR 1997), Ireland & Lennox (JAAF 2002) • Chaney et al. (TAR 2004) is an exception • Can we identify good “instruments” in accounting research? • Larcker & Rusticus (SSRN WP) are skeptical • If there’s reason to think selection exists, an alternative is to control through research design choices • e.g., matched pairs, or samples limited to smaller clients
Moving Beyond the Big-Small Dichotomy Differentiation within the dominant Big 4 group
Within-Big 4 Differentiation • In past, Big 4 viewed as homogenous group • B4 (90%) & NB4 (10%) U.S. market shares • Low power due to small variance in auditor type • May be more variation within Big 4 firms • Some plausible within-Big 4 variations: • Industry expertise • Geographical variation • Offices (cross-city differences) • Countries (cross-country differences)
Industry Expertise • Firms actively promote their industry expertise • Industry experts have more experience and appear to make better audit judgments • Solomon et al. (JAR 1999); Low (TAR 2004) • Auditor clienteles proxy for industry expertise • More clients create more opportunities to acquire deep industry knowledge/expertise • Industry shares are not evenly distributed • Using 2000-2001 U.S. fee data & 2-digit SIC codes • #1 firm has 50% of industry fees, #2 firm only 22% • Leadership among Big 5 firms for 63 industries • AA (14), DT (5), EY (16), KPMG (9), PWC (19)
Evidence from Audit Fees • Big 4 industry leaders have higher fees (10-30%) and higher fees imply higher quality audits • Financial statement outcomes evidence higher quality audits by Big 4 industry leaders • Smaller abnormal accruals (less discretion) • Balsam et al. (APJT 2003), Krishnan (AH 2003) • Higher valuation of earnings surprises • Balsam et al. (AJPT 2003) • Less fraudulent reporting (AAERs) • Carcello & Nagy (2004 Managerial Auditing Journal) • Less IPO underpricing and smaller accruals • Elder and Zhou (2003 WP)
What is an Accounting Firm? What’s the relevant unit of analysis? Individual offices, national practices, or international operations?
Arguments for an Office-Level Analysis • Accounting firms are decentralized networks of quasi-independent practice offices • Engagement partners in local offices contract and administer audits to clients in the same locale • Issue audit reports on office letterhead • Francis et al. (ABACUS 1999); Reynolds & Francis (JAE 2000); Ferguson et al. (TAR 2003) • Client influence/fee dependence is stronger at the office level • Enron < 2% of Andersen fees nationally • Over 30% of Houston office fees
First Office-Level StudyReynolds & Francis (JAE 2000) • Auditors are more conservative for larger clients in U.S. practice offices • They issue more GC audit reports • Clients have smaller abnormal accruals • Client size measured “relative” to office clienteles • Client size is not significant using national clienteles to measure relative client size • Conclusion • Office-level data provides better understanding • No results using aggregate data; but evidence of auditor conservatism using office-level data
Office-Level Reputation for Industry Expertise • Is industry expertise firm-wide (national), office-specific (city), or combination of both? • Office-specific arguments • Deep expertise is client-specific and cannot be fully captured by firms and distributed across offices • Gilson & Mnookin (SLR 1985), law firms • Firm-wide arguments • Standardized training/audit practices and knowledge sharing is possible across offices
How is National Versus City Industry Leadership Priced? • 4 possibilities(Francis et al., TAR 2005) • Engagements where auditor is both the national and the city-specific industry leader • 18% of US sample • Engagements where auditor is a national industry leader (alone) • 10% of US sample • Engagements where auditor is a city-specific industry leaders (alone) • 23% of US sample • Nonleaders (neither city/national leaders) • 49% of US sample
Evidence • Joint national-city #1 has +28% premium • City-alone #1 has +10% premium • National-alone #1 has no fee premium relative to nonleaders (default group is nonleaders) • Implication - audit quality is office-specific • Industry premia only when a city leader • Either alone or joint national-city leader • National market share is driven by city leadership • National #1, 86% of fees where city leader
RQ - Does City Leadership Affect Earnings Quality? • Follow-up WP to Francis et al. (TAR 2005) • Uses same B5 sample from 2000-01 first-time cycle of fee disclosures to measure industry leaders • What do we find? • Clients of city industry leaders have smaller abnormal accruals, and smaller income-increasing accruals • Magnitude is 6-12% of pre-tax earnings • Clients of joint national-city leaders are less likely to meet or beat by +1 cent analysts’ forecasts (40% 29%) • City-only leaders are also less likely to do so (40% 33%) • In both tests results for national leaders (alone) are n.s.
Legal Systems and Differential Auditing(over time/countries) • Institutions & legal regimes affect auditor incentives • Two research approaches • A regime change within a single country (over time) • The Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995 • Lee and Mande (AJPT 2003), Francis & Krishnan (APJAE 2003) • Cross-country studies of different legal regimes • Seetharaman, Gul and Lyn (JAE 2002) • higher audit fees of UK firms cross-listed in US • implies higher fees due to increased litigation risk exposure • Khurana et al. (TAR 2004) • B4 clients have lower COC in US (but not Australia, UK, Canada) • Implies US litigation risk drives B4 behavior (not reputations)
RQ – Do B4 incentives vary across legal regimes? • Do B4 audits vary across jurisdictions? • Three Scenarios • Big 4 are uniform around the world • Incentives to maintain brand name (standardization) • U.S. is an outlier due to extreme liability exposure • More lawsuits in US than rest of world combined • Big 4 conservatism is increasing in country-level investor protection and auditor litigation risk
Uniform Worldwide U.S. Outlier Big 4 Auditor Conservatism High Conservatism Low Low High (U.S.) Legal Liability/Investor Protection
Preliminary Results Indicate that Legal Regime Matters • Big 4 conservatism is • Increasing in investor protection/litigation risk • Holds both with/without U.S. observations • Implies less discretion to manage earnings • Magnitude • Abnormal accruals are smaller by around 5% of earnings in common law countries with stronger investor protection • Non-Big 4 firms are uniform across countries (and less conservative than Big 4) • Less incentive for reputation protection/litigation avoidance behavior (same as within US)
Other Examples of Research on Audit Quality Auditor tenure Non-audit services (NAS) Audit committees/corporate governance Accounting firm alumni
Auditor Tenure • Tenure and mandatory auditor rotation • Long tenure is good because auditors know more about the client (deeper knowledge) • Long tenure is bad because of entrenchment and self-serving bias • The evidence to date: • Audit quality is lower in first 3 years • Johnson et al. (CAR 2002) • But longer tenure (5+ years) increases audit quality • Meyer et al. (TAR 2003) • Studies of partner tenure in Australia and Taiwan • Office level analysis
Nonaudit Services (NAS) • Do NAS impair auditor independence? • More fee dependence • Inherent conflict of interest • SEC attempted to ban NAS in 2000 • Profession’s defense • Increases auditor’s knowledge • Clients demand and value NAS • Incentives exist to protect reputations for independence
Evidence • Frankel, Johnson & Nelson (TAR 2002) • Compelling set of results against NAS • Firms with higher NAS are associated with more earnings management: • Larger abnormal accruals (more discretion) • More likely to meet analysts’ earnings targets • But also counter-evidence • Ashbaugh et al. (TAR 2003), Chung & Kallapur (TAR 2003), Reynolds et al. (AJPT 2004), DeFond et al. (JAR 2003), Larcker & Richardson (JAR 2004)
Broader Implications • Accounting journals generally don’t publish replications and no-result studies • But replications show fragility and sensitivity to design choices • e.g., Frankel et al. (TAR 2002) & Ashbaugh et al. (TAR 2003) get different results on main tests, but with slightly different samples/models
Audit Quality and Corporate Boards/Governance • Audit quality is better when strong boards and audit committees exist (independence/outside directors) • Auditors are more likely to issue GC reports • Carcello and Neal (TAR 2000) • Less likely to be replaced following GC report • Carcello and Neal (TAR 2003) • Auditors are more likely to detect fraud • Dechow et al. (CAR 1995) • Accruals are smaller (less earnings management) • Klein (JAE 2002), Bedard et al. (AJPT 2004) • Auditors have higher audit fees and are less likely to perform non-audit services • Abbot et al. (SSRN 2001), Abbott et al. (AJPT 2003)
Accounting Firm Alumni and Auditor Independence • Outplacement to clients impairs audit quality • Clients know the auditor’s methods too well • Auditor is cozy with former colleagues • Lennox (JAE 2005) • Outplacement is less than perceived (10%) • But GC reports are less frequent than predicted (suggests client leniency) • Menon & Williams (TAR 2004) • Firms with alumni have larger abnormal accruals
Policy Making What’s the role of academic auditing research on audit quality?
The U.S. Experience • Academic research has little influence on regulation and policy-making • Two recent examples that ignored research • SEC’s proposed ban on NAS in 2000 • Arthur Levitt was convinced a ban was needed • Quick adoption of Sarbanes-Oxley (SOX) in 2002 • Political cover following Enron/Worldcom scandals