350 likes | 381 Views
Explore the economics of the art industry with insights on auctions, masterpiece investments, and market segments. Discover the Mei-Moses Art Index and the correlation between art and finance. Unravel the mysteries of high-value artworks and the unique challenges of the art market.
E N D
Entertainment and Media: Markets and Economics The Art Market
$135 Million Klimt, to Ronald Lauder http://www.nytimes.com/2006/06/19/arts/design/19klim.html?ex=1308369600&en=37eb32381038a749&ei=5088&partner=rssnyt&emc=rss
Going Once: $43.7M It looks like it should be worth $200, but it sold for a whopping $43.7 million. An Andy Warhol painting called "200 One Dollar Bills" fetched the megasum at Sotheby's last night. It represented an incredible profit for the seller, who purchased the silkscreen for $385,000 in 1986, according to a spokeswoman for the Upper East Side auction house. Sotheby's had estimated it would sell for $12 million. http://www.nypost.com/p/news/local/manhattan/item_ZEdwTB6wV7tjoBRazvCIOO
Going Twice …. $80M Jasper Johns: 1988:$17M to 2006:$80M
$100 Million … sort of Stephen Wynn with a Prized Possession, 2007
An Enduring Art Mystery Graphics show relative sizes of the two works. The Persistence of Econometrics. Greene, 2008 Why do larger paintings command higher prices? The Persistence of Memory. Salvador Dali, 1931
Dali in Large and Small Hallucinogenic Torreador (1969-1970) is 9’10” wide and 13’1” tall. The Persistence of Memory. Salvador Dali, 1931. 9” x 11”
Monet in Large and Small Sale prices of 328 signed Monet paintings Log of $price = a + b log surface area + e
Entertainment and Media: Markets and Economics Art as a Financial Asset
Art Market • Market for paintings? • Subjective “returns” • Consumption value • Measuring the return to art • Ill defined “asset” • Uniqueness of valuable pieces • Repeat sales of the same print after long intervals (hundreds are recorded)
Paintings as Risky Investments Annualized Returns 1900 – 1986 Mean Std.Dev. Correlations
Very Long Term Return to Art • Van Gogh’s Irises • 1987: $40M • 1990: $53M (sort of…) • Getty museum, which won’t tell how much… • Lauder’s $135M Klimt • Baumol’s analysis of 640 transactions 1652-1961 • Remarkably low annual return – close to zero • High variance. • Returns to art are all aesthetic
Anti-Portfolio Theory (Pesando) • Buy one masterpiece for $100,000, not ten lesser pieces at $10,000 each. (Wisdom) • Conclusions • Short run excess returns • Masterpiece portfolio does not do better than the market • Many price and return anomalies
Crapshoot Theory • Baumol: There is no equilibrium and no anchor • Why are money and art correlated? • A wealth effect. • An Intervening effect – the stock market • An issue of causation • The greater fool theory
A few weeks ago, a triptych portrait by the British modernist painter Francis Bacon sold for $142.4 million, a record for a work of art at auction. The next night, a silk-screen print, “Silver Car Crash (Double Disaster),” by the American pop artist Andy Warhol brought $105.4 million. And this week, “Saying Grace,” by the American illustrator Norman Rockwell, sold for $46..1 million. The art market would seem to be going through the roof. But is it?
Mei-Moses Art Index http://www.artasanasset.com/main/ (You need to be a member to get past the front page.)
Mei and Moses on Art • 1950- auctions, Christies and Sothebys • Underperformance of masterpieces • Better than fixed income securities, worse than stocks • Small variance good portfolio choice • Loose ends • Winner’s curse in bids? • Income effect – cyclicality of prices • Euphoria effect – movement with stock market • The true return – intangibles
How does art attain value? This article describes a new vault where buyers of high end art can store their assets while they wait for them to become more valuable.
Entertainment and Media: Markets and Economics Art Auctions and Antitrust
Art, Auctions and Antitrust • Art Auctions • Open outcry, English style (ascending) • Private information only in valuation (by nature) • High end art market dominated (90%) by Sotheby’s and Christies
Some History • NY, 1960, dominated by Parke-Bernet • Competition from London by Sotheby • P-B for sale in 1963, $2M. • S makes a credible threat to enter, drives the price down to $1.5M and enters • Christies and Phillips enter in 1977 • Christies entry did not drive down the value of Sotheby. Entry established NY as a focal point for art sale – drove up the stock value of both companies. • S and C acted as a natural duopoly, heavy competition until 1995. Competition suddenly stopped. • 1995, conspired to fix commissions.
Art Auction Conventions • The “hammer price” • Two commissions wedged between buyer and seller: • Buyer’s commission about 10% of hammer price • Seller’s commission about 10% of hammer price Seller Hammer Buyer Commission
Fixed Commissions Sotheby’s essentially identical.
The Civil Settlement • About $300M for each company • Some criminal penalties for some conspirators (notably Alfred Taubman who lost a lot - $7.5M and 10 months in jail.) • Most $$$ paid (inappropriately) to buyers • Theory is unambiguous – buyers will just reduce their bids so that bid+commission will not exceed their reservation price. They were not harmed. • A curious incentive – the amnesty rule. The first company to confess gets off (partly) from the criminal prosecution. (Not the civil suit.) • A curious auction: The right to represent the plaintiffs was auctioned to the firm with the highest guess as to the minimum they believed they could win for the plaintiffs. (David Boies et al.)