980 likes | 1.11k Views
Chapter Twenty-Two. Introduction. While the economy can and does move away from long-run equilibrium, it has a natural self-correcting mechanism. It returns it to the point where resources are being used at their normal rates and Gaps between current and potential output disappear.
E N D
Introduction • While the economy can and does move away from long-run equilibrium, it has a natural self-correcting mechanism. • It returns it to the point where resources are being used at their normal rates and • Gaps between current and potential output disappear.
Introduction • Why is it that output and inflation vary from quarter to quarter and year to year? • What determines the extent of the fluctuations? • Figure 22.1 illustrates the long-run trends in the U.S. inflation rate over the past 50 years. • It also displays a series of shaded bars representing recessions.
Introduction • While there is no apparent relationship between the level of inflation and these recessions, it does appear that the inflation rate: • Falls when the economy is contracting. • Rises when it is expanding. • At least that is what happens most of the time. • But in general there appears to be a connection between growth and changes in inflation.
Introduction • In recent years, the frequency of recessions has fallen. • Recessions used to occur once every five years. • Now they occur on average about every eight years. • This reduction in the volatility of real growth has been called the “Great Moderation.”
Introduction • In this chapter we will: • Catalogue the various reasons that the dynamic aggregate demand curve and the aggregate supply curve shift. • Examine what happens during the transition as the economy moves to long-run equilibrium. • Use the model to understand how central bankers work to achieve their stabilization objectives.
Introduction • We will also examine: • How policymakers work to achieve their stabilization goals; • The appropriate actions to take when potential output changes; and • The difficulty central bankers have figuring out why output has fallen.
Sources of Fluctuations in Output and Inflation • Remember that long-run equilibrium means: • Y = YP output = potential output. • = T inflation = target inflation. • = e inflation = expected inflation. • Short-run equilibrium means: • The dynamic aggregate demand curve (AD) and the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve cross.
Sources of Fluctuations in Output and Inflation • Immediately after either the SRAS curve or AD curve shift, the economy will move away from its long-run equilibrium. • Understanding short-run fluctuations in output and inflation requires that we study shifts in AD and SRAS.
Sources of Fluctuations in Output and Inflation • In this chapter we will be looking at shocks. • Economists define shocks as something unexpected, for example, an increase in oil prices or change in consumer confidence. • A shock shifts the AD or SRAS curve. • Because it affects costs of production, the oil price increase is a supply shock. • A change in consumer confidence affects consumption expenditure so it is a demand shock.
Shifts in the Dynamic Aggregate Demand Curve • Recall that a shift in the AD curve can be cause by either: • A shift in the monetary policy reaction curve or • A change in components that are not sensitive to the interest rate that shifts aggregate expenditure, for example, government spending.
A Decline in the Central Bank’s Inflation Target • Over the past several decades, numerous countries have succeeded in reducing their inflation rates from fairly high levels to the modest ones we see today. • All of these changes involved permanent declines in inflation that must have been a result of a decrease in the central bank’s inflation target.
A Decline in the Central Bank’s Inflation Target • To analyze this, we begin with the monetary policy reaction curve. • A fall in T shifts the monetary policy reaction curve to the left. • The decrease in the inflation target raises the real interest rate policymakers set at each level of inflation. • This reduces aggregate expenditure shifting the AD curve to the left as well. • The economy moves to a new short-run equilibrium.
A Decline in the Central Bank’s Inflation Target • The new short-run equilibrium at 2 has inflation and current output lower than they were prior to the monetary policy tightening. • This creates a recessionary gap: Y < YP. • There is now downward pressure on production costs. • This shifts SRAS to the right. • The new long-run equilibrium at 3 is where inflation equals the central bank’s new target and output equals potential output.
An Increase in Government Purchases • What are the macroeconomic implications of a large expansionary move in fiscal policy? • An increase in G shifts the AD curve to the right. • The economy moves from the original short-run equilibrium point 1 to a new short-run equilibrium point 2. • The immediate impact is to raise both current output and inflation.
An Increase in Government Purchases • Because potential output has not changed, this is not the long-run effect. • The higher level of current output means that there is an expansionary gap: Y > YP. • Firms increase both their product prices and wages more than they would at normal output. • This shifts the SRAS curve to the left, driving inflation even higher.
An Increase in Government Purchases • As inflation increases, monetary policymakers raise the real interest rate, moving the economy along the AD curve. • Output begins to fall back toward its long-run equilibrium level, potential output. • The economy settles at point 3. • Note, however, that inflation is higher at 3 than it was at 1. • This is above the policymakers’ original inflation target, T.
An Increase in Government Purchases • So long as monetary policymakers remain committed to their original inflation target, they need to do something to get the economy back to the point where it began. • In this case, tighter monetary policy shifts the AD curve to the left. • This brings the economy back to the long-run equilibrium where output equals potential output and inflation equals the central bank’s target.
An Increase in Government Purchases • Without a change in target inflation, an increase in government purchases causes a temporary increase in both output and inflation.
A Decline in Aggregate Expenditure • A decline in aggregate expenditure has the opposite effect of an increase in government spending. • The AD curve shifts to the left, driving output down. • A decline in aggregate expenditure causes a temporary decline in both output and inflation. • In the absence of any monetary policy response, the recessionary output gap causes the SRAS curve to shift to the right.
A Decline in Aggregate Expenditure • The shift in the SRAS curve drives inflation down future and current output begins to rise toward potential. • If policymakers do not react, inflation and output will return to their original long-run levels.
Shifts in the Dynamic Aggregate Demand Curve - Examples • In response to increases in government spending during the escalation of the Vietnam War in the late 1960s, • The Fed simply allowed inflation to rise. • What could have been a temporary increase in inflation became a permanent one.
Shifts in the Dynamic Aggregate Demand Curve • Large tax cuts in 2001 and rise in defense spending associated with the war in Iraq did not have the same impact at in the 1960s. • The fiscal stimulus came at a time when the economy was weakening for other reasons. • The Fed had learned the important lesson that it may need to raise interest rates to counter the risk of inflation from expansionary fiscal policy.
Shifts in Short-Run Aggregate Supply • Changes in production costs shift the SRAS curve. • What are the effects of an increase in the costs of production - a negative supply shock? • Ex: Increase in price of oil. • Immediately the SRAS curve shifts left. • These are bad consequences: higher inflation and lower growth
Shifts in Short-Run Aggregate Supply • The short-run equilibrium moves to point 2 where the new SRAS curve meets AD. • This creates a condition referred to as stagflation. • Economic stagnation coupled with increased inflation. • The recessionary gap puts downward pressure on production costs and inflation.
Shifts in Short-Run Aggregate Supply • As a result of the recessionary gap, the SRAS curve begins to shift right. • This drives inflation down and output up. • This continues until the economy returns to potential output and the central bank’s target inflation level.
Shifts in Short-Run Aggregate Supply • As with an increase in government purchases, a supply shock has no effect on the economy’s long-run equilibrium point. • A supply shock causes inflation to rise temporarily and then fall. • This happens at the same time that current output falls temporarily and then rises. • In the long run, the economy returns to the point where output equals potential output and inflation equals the central bank’s target.
A recession is a decline in activity, not just a dip in growth rate. • Exact length is ambiguous. • Dating the peaks and troughs involves judgment. • Table 22.3 displays the results of the NBER’s analyses of the business cycle since the end of WWII. • Recessions differ along several dimensions: depth, duration, and diffusion.
Using the Aggregate Demand-Aggregate Supply Framework We examine the following: • How do policymakers achieve their stabilization objectives? • What accounts for the “Great Moderation”? • What happens when potential output changes? • What are the implications of globalization for monetary policy? • Can policymakers distinguish a recessionary gap from a fall in potential output? • Can policymakers stabilize output and inflation simultaneously?
How Do Policymakers Achieve Their Stabilization Objectives? • The aggregate demand-aggregate supply framework is useful in understanding how monetary and fiscal policymakers seek to stabilize output and inflation using stabilization policy. • When shifting their reaction curve, central bankers shift AD. • They cannot shift the SRAS curve. • This means monetary policymakers can neutralize demand shocks, but cannot offset supply shocks.
How Do Policymakers Achieve Their Stabilization Objectives? • Nevertheless, positive supply shocks that raise output and lower inflation provide policymakers with an opportunity. • Following a positive supply shock, central bankers can guide the economy to a new, lower inflation target without inducing a recessionary output gap.
How Do Policymakers Achieve Their Stabilization Objectives? • As for fiscal policy, our macroeconomic framework allows us to study the impact of changes in government taxes and expenditures as well. • The active use of fiscal policy faces great challenges. • The conclusion is that stabilization policy is usually best left to central bankers.
Monetary Policy • What happens if consumers and businesses suddenly become more pessimistic about the future? • This shifts the AD curve to the left. • Output falls below potential causing a recessionary gap.
Monetary Policy • Drop in consumer or business confidence: • AD0 AD1 • Economy 12 • Stabilization requires shifting AD back towhere it started.
Monetary Policy • Policymakers will conclude that the long-run real interest rate has fallen. • If the inflation target stays the same, the drop in aggregate expenditure prompts them to shift the monetary policy reaction curve to the right. • This reduces the level of the real interest rate. • The AD curve now shifts right, back to its original level. • The policy response means the economy will be back at long run equilibrium.
Monetary Policy • In practice, it is extremely difficult to keep inflation and output from fluctuating when aggregate expenditure changes. • There are two reasons: • It takes time to recognize what has happened. • Changes in interest rates do not have an immediate impact on the economy. • While in theory we can neutralize aggregate demand shocks, in reality they create short-run fluctuations in output and inflation.
Stability improves welfare. • Individuals strive to stabilize consumption, but it can be difficult. • When income falls temporarily you can: • Draw on savings (emergency funds) or • Borrow using credit. • But credit is only a stop-gap measure. • The financial crisis of 2007-2009 demonstrates how risky credit can be.
Discretionary Fiscal Policy • There are two types of fiscal policy: • Automatic stabilizers. • Automatic stabilizers operate without any further actions on the part of the government. • Ex: unemployment insurance and the proportional nature of the tax system. • Discretionary policy. • Discretionary policy relies on fiscal policymakers’ decisions. • Discretionary policy changes aggregate expenditures shifting the dynamic aggregate demand curve.
Discretionary Fiscal Policy • Fiscal policy can act just like monetary policy to offset shifts in the dynamic aggregate demand curve and stabilize inflation and output. • On closer examination, however, it has at least two shortcomings: • Discretionary fiscal policy works slowly, and • It is almost impossible to implement effectively.