1 / 44

Modern trade theory: Increasing returns to scale and Imperfections

Modern trade theory: Increasing returns to scale and Imperfections. Dr. Petre Badulescu. Topics to be covered. Basics of Imperfect Competition 2. Trade under monopolistic competition

Download Presentation

Modern trade theory: Increasing returns to scale and Imperfections

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Modern trade theory: Increasing returns to scale and Imperfections Dr. Petre Badulescu

  2. Topics to be covered • Basics of Imperfect Competition • 2. Trade under monopolistic competition • - Use the experience of the North American Free Trade Agreement to assess the predictions of the monopolistic competition model • 3. Intra-Industry Trade and the Gravity Equation Lecture 6, International economics

  3. Introduction In this lecture we examine a model in which countries benefit from free international trade when there is increasing returns to scale in production and imperfect competition. Producers gain by moving down their average cost curve and consumers are able to enjoy more product varieties. Increasing returns to scale: A technological situation in which proportionate increases in the use of productive inputs lead to greater than proportionate increases in output. Lecture 6, International economics

  4. Introduction • Why does a country simultaneously export and import similar types of products? • To answer this question we introduce a new explanation for trade based on the model of monopolistic competition in this lecture. • In perfectly competitive markets, the goods produced are homogeneous. In this lecture, we assume that goods are differentiated, and allow for imperfect competition. Lecture 6, International economics

  5. Introduction • In this lecture we examine: • The basics of the monopolistic competition model. • How consumer choices and prices are affected under monopolistic competition when trade opens between two countries. • The gains from international trade under monopolistic competition. • The gains and adjustment costs for Mexico and the United States under NAFTA. • The gravity equation, which states that countries with higher GDP, or that are close, will trade more. Lecture 6, International economics

  6. Introduction • Most goods are differentiated goods, that is, they are not identical. • When we allow for imperfect competition, firms can influence the price they charge. • Monopolistic competition has two key features: • The goods produced by different firms are differentiated. • Firms enjoy increasing returns to scale, by which we mean that the average costs for a firm fall as more output is produced. Lecture 6, International economics

  7. Introduction • Intra-industry trade deals with imports and exports in the same industry. • Large countries (as measured by their GDP) should trade the most. This is the prediction of the gravity equation. • The monopolistic competition model also helps us to understand the effects of free-trade agreements, in which free trade occurs among a group of countries. • Next, we will compare and contrast the cases of monopoly and duopoly, specifically, the demand characteristics in each type of market. Lecture 6, International economics

  8. Basics of Imperfect Competition Monopoly Equilibrium The extra revenue earned from selling one more unit is called the marginal revenue. FIGURE 6-1 Monopoly Equilibrium The monopolist chooses the profit-maximizing quantity, QM, at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost. From that quantity, we trace up to the demand curve and over to the price axis to see that the monopolist charges the price PM > MR = MC. The monopoly equilibrium is at point A. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  9. Basics of Imperfect Competition Demand with Duopoly FIGURE 6-2 (2 of 2) Demand Curves with Duopoly Alternatively, if the products are differentiated, the firm that lowers its price will take some, but not all, sales from the other firm; it will face the demand curve, d,and at P2it will sell Q4at point C′. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  10. Trade under monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model of monopolistic competition: • 1. Each firm produces a good that is similar to but slightly differentiated from the goods that other firms in the industry produce. • Each firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve for its product and has some control over the price it charges. Lecture 6, International economics

  11. Trade under monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model of monopolistic competition: 2. There are many firms in the industry. • If the number of firms is N, then D/N is the share of demand that each firm faces when the firms are all charging the same price. • When only one firm lowers its price, however, it will face a flatter demand curve d. Lecture 6, International economics

  12. Trade under monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model of monopolistic competition: 3. Firms produce using a technology with increasing returns to scale. A production technology in which the average costs of production fall as the quantity produced increase FIGURE 6-3 Increasing Returns to Scale This diagram shows the average cost, AC, and marginal cost, MC, of a firm. Increasing returns to scale cause average costs to fall as the quantity produced increases. Marginal cost is below average cost and is drawn as constant for simplicity. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  13. Trade under monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model of monopolistic competition: NumericalExample of Increasing Returns to Scale TABLE 6-2 Cost Information for the Firm This table illustrates increasing returns to scale, in which average costs fall as quantity rises. Whenever the price charged is above AC, then a firm earns monopoly profits. Lecture 6, International economics

  14. Trade under monopolistic competition Assumptions of the model of monopolistic competition: 4. Because firms can enter and exit the industry freely, monopoly profits are zero in the long run. • Firms will enter as long as it is possible to make monopoly profits, and the more firms that enter, the lower profits per firm become. • Profits for each firm end up as zero in the long run, just as in perfect competition. Lecture 6, International economics

  15. Trade under monopolistic competition • Next, we will examine monopolistic competition: • in the short run, without trade. • in the long run, without trade. • in the short run, with free trade. • in the long run with free trade. Lecture 6, International economics

  16. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium without international trade Short-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-4 Short-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibrium without Trade The short-runequilibrium under monopolistic competition is the same as a monopoly equilibrium. The firm chooses to produce the profit maximizing quantity Q0at whichthe firm’s marginal revenue, mr0, equals itsmarginal cost, MC. The price charged is P0. Because price exceeds average cost, the firm makes monopoly profits. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  17. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium without international trade Long-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-5 (1 of 2) Long-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibriumwithout Trade Drawn by the possibility of making profits in the short-runequilibrium, new firms enter the industry and the firm’s demand curve, d0, shifts to the left and becomes more elastic (i.e., flatter), shown by d1. The long-run equilibrium under monopolistic competition occurs at the quantity Q1 where the marginal revenue curve, mr1 (associated with demand curve d1), equals marginal cost. At that quantity, the no-trade price, PA, equals average costs at point A. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  18. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium without international trade Long-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-5 (2 of 2) Long-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibriumwithout Trade In the long-run equilibrium, firms earn zero monopoly profits and there is no entry or exit. The quantity produced by each firm is less than in short-run equilibrium (Figure 6-4). Q1 is less than Q0 because new firms have entered the industry. With a greater number of firms and hence more varieties available to consumers, the demand for each variety d1 is less then d0. The demand curve D/NA shows the no-trade demand when all firms charge the same price. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  19. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Short-RunEquilibrium • Assume Home and Foreign are exactly the same. • Same number of consumers • Same technology and cost curves • Same number of firms in the no-trade equilibrium • Given the above conditions, if there were no economies of scale, there would be no reason for trade. Similarly, • Under the Ricardo model, countries with identical technologies would not trade. • Under the Heckscher-Ohlin model, countries with identical factor endowments would not trade. However, under monopolistic competition, two identical countries will still engage in free international trade. Lecture 6, International economics

  20. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Short-RunEquilibrium • The number of firms in the no-trade equilibrium in each country is NA. • First, we will consider each country in long-run equilibrium without trade • When trade opens, the number of customers available to each firm doubles. • Since there are twice as many consumers, but also twice as many firms, the ratio stays the same. • The product varieties also double. • With the greater number of varieties available, the demand for each individual variety will be more elastic. Lecture 6, International economics

  21. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Short-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-6 (1 of 2) Short-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibriumwith free trade When trade is opened, the larger market makes the firm’s demand curve more elastic, as shown by d2 (with corresponding marginal revenue curve, mr2). The firm chooses to produce the quantity Q2 at which marginal revenue equals marginal costs; this quantity corresponds to a price of P2. With sales of Q2 at price P2, the firm will make monopoly profits because price is greater than AC. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  22. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Short-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-6(2 of 2) Short-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibrium with free trade When allfirms lower their prices to P2, however, the relevant demand curve is D/NA, which indicates that they can sell only Q′2 at price P2. At this short-runequilibrium (point B′), price is less than average cost and all firms incur losses. As a result, some firms are forced to exit the industry. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  23. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Long-RunEquilibrium • Since firms are making losses, some of them will exit the industry. • Firm exit will increase demand for the remaining firms’ products and decrease the available product varieties to consumers. • We now have NT firms which is fewer than the NA firms we had before. • The new demand D/NT lies to the right of D/NA. Lecture 6, International economics

  24. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Long-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-7 (1 of 2) Long-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibriumwith free trade The long-run equilibrium with free trade occurs at point C: the demand curve d3 facing an individual firm is tangent to the AC curve, and mr3 =MC. At this point, profits are maximized for each firm producing Q3(which satisfies mr3 =MC) and charging price PW (which equals AC). Since monopoly profits are zero when price equals average cost, no firms enter or exit the industry. 0 How does this long-run equilibrium compare to that withoutinternational trade? Lecture 6, International economics

  25. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Long-RunEquilibrium FIGURE 6-7 (2 of 2) Long-Run Monopolistic Competition Equilibriumwith free trade (continued) Compared with the long-run equilibriumwithouttrade (Figure 6-5), d3 (along with mr3) has shifted out as domestic firms exited the industry and has become more elastic due to the greater total number of varieties with trade, 2NT > NA. Compared with the long-run equilibrium without trade at point A, the trade equilibrium at point C has a lower price and higher sales by all surviving firms. 0 Lecture 6, International economics

  26. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Gains from free international trade • The long-run equilibrium at point C has two sources of gains from trade for consumers: • A drop in price. • The lower price is a result of increased productivity of the surviving firms coming from increasing returns to scale. • Gains from trade to consumers. • Although there are fewer product varieties made within each country (by fewer firms), consumers have more product variety because they can choose products of the firms from both countries after trade. Lecture 6, International economics

  27. Trade under monopolistic competition Equilibrium with free international trade Adjustment costs from free international trade • There are adjustment costs associated with monopolistic competition, as some firms shut down or exit the industry. • Workers in those firms experience a spell of unemployment. • Over the long run, however, we could expect those workers to find new jobs, so these costs are temporary. • We will examine both short-run and long-run adjustment costs. • Next, to test the predictions of the monopolistic competition model, we look at evidence from Mexico, Canada, and the United States following the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Lecture 6, International economics

  28. NAFTA • The monopolistic competition model predicts that a reduction to trade barriers between countries should have disruptive effects in the short-run and gains from trade in the long-run. • The disruptive effects in the short-run include employment losses as some firms go out of market. • In the long run, however, employment should recover as surviving firms expand into foreign markets. As firms expand into foreign markets, consumers gain access to increased variety, and a larger size of surviving firms allows them to better exploit increasing returns to scale. • This latter effect should appear in the data as an increase in productivity and an increase in real wages as the prices charged by firms fall. • Much of the model’s predictions are supported by the experience of the three countries that participated in NAFTA. Lecture 6, International economics

  29. NAFTA • This free trade agreement (FTA) eliminated most tariffs and other barriers to trade among the countries of Canada, Mexico, and the United States. • As expected, the short-run effects of the FTA proved to be quite disruptive. For instance, NAFTA led to a sharp decrease in Canadian employment in manufacturing. This job loss was followed by a sharp increase in Canadian manufacturing productivity as firms expanded their exports to the American market, and the increase in productivity also appears to have increased real wages in Canada. • The productivity effects were also substantial in Mexico, although many of the positive effects of NAFTA appear to have been obscured by a deep recession caused by a financial crisis. Lecture 6, International economics

  30. NAFTA • In the U.S., NAFTA was associated with a modest loss of work in certain industries that was offset in part by the expansion of the trade adjustment assistance program for those workers whose jobs disappeared due to NAFTA. This program is specially designed for exactly the disruptive effects of trade. • In the long-run, American consumers have benefited from NAFTA as the number of varieties made available as trade with Mexico expanded. On net, the gain from free international trade with Mexico are calculated to exceed the losses. Lecture 6, International economics

  31. NAFTA Summary of NAFTA • The monopolistic competition model has two sources of gains from trade: • The rise in productivity due to expanded output by surviving firms, which leads to lower prices, and • The expansion in the overall number of varieties of products available to consumers with trade, despite the exit of some firms in each country. • For the U.S., the long-run gains have consisted of an expansion of varieties, and a fall in consumer prices. • It is clear that for Canada and the U.S., the long-run gains considerably exceed the short-run costs. • In Mexico, the gains have not translated into the growth of real wages for workers. • However, the real earnings of higher-income workers in the maquiladora sector have risen. They have been the principal beneficiaries of NAFTA so far. Lecture 6, International economics

  32. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation • Here I will show that the monopolistic competition model is helpful in understanding key parts of international trading patterns. • For example, the monopolistic competition model predicts that • intra-industry trade should be highest in industries in which there is a high degree of product differentiation. • The index of intra-industry trade measures the extent to which trade is two-way between countries. As predicted by the monopolistic competition model, • the index is high for goods that also exhibit a high degree of product differentiation. Lecture 6, International economics

  33. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation Index of intra-industry trade The index of intra-industry trade tells us what proportion of trade in each product involves both imports and exports: a high index (up to 100%) indicates that an equal amount of the good is imported and exported, whereas a low index (0%) indicates that the good is either imported or exported but not both. Lecture 6, International economics

  34. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation The gravity equation The monopolistic competition model predicts that international trade patterns should be well predicted by a gravity equation. • Jan Tinbergen, Dutch economist and Nobel laureate, was trained in physics and thought of comparing the trade between countries to the force of gravity between objects. • In physics, objects with a larger mass, or those that are close together, have greater gravitational pull between them. • In economics, the gravity equation for trade states that countries with larger GDPs, or that are close to each other, will have more trade between them. Lecture 6, International economics

  35. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation The gravity equation Newton’s Universal Law of Gravitation • Suppose you have two objects with masses, M1 and M2 and are located distance d apart. • The force of gravity between these two masses is: • The larger the objects are or the closer they are, the greater the force of gravity between them. • In the case of trade, the larger the two countries are, or the closer they are, the greater the amount of trade. Lecture 6, International economics

  36. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation The gravity equation Newton’s Universal Law of Gravitation The Gravity Equation in Trade Deriving the Gravity Equation Lecture 6, International economics

  37. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation The gravity equation • The gravity equation predicts that the volume of trade between two countries (here countries 1 and 2) is increasing in the gross domestic product of either country and it is decreasing in their distance from each other. • This relationship comes from the fact that each country produces a distinct set of varieties that are demanded in each country. The share of a country’s GDP (the value of the output of its varieties) that is sold to a given foreign country is increasing in the foreign country’s income or GDP and decreasing in distance between the two countries because of transport costs rise with distance. • The gravity equation is an accurate predictor of the volume of trade between countries. Lecture 6, International economics

  38. Intra-industry trade and the Gravity equation The gravity equation • The gravity equation has important implications for the monopolistic competition model with trade. • Larger countries export more because they produce more product varieties, and import more because their demand is higher. • The demand for Country 1’s goods depends on: • The relative size of the importing country • The distance between the two countries • To measure the relative size of a country, we use its share of world GDP: • Share2 = GDP2/GDPW Lecture 6, International economics

  39. APPLICATION The Gravity Equation for Canada and the United States, 1993 Plotted in these figures are the dollar value of exports in 1993 and the gravity term (plotted in log scale). Panel (a) shows these variables for trade between 10 Canadian provinces and 30 U.S. states. When the gravity term is 1, for example, the amount of trade between a province and state is $93 million. Panel (b) shows these variables for trade between 10 Canadian provinces. When the gravity term is 1, the amount of trade between the provinces is $1.3 billion, 14 times larger than between a province and a state. These graphs illustrate two important points: there is a positive relationship between country size (as measured by GDP) and trade volume, and there is much more trade within Canada than between Canada and the United States. Lecture 6, International economics

  40. APPLICATION The Gravity Equation for Canada and the United States If trade across borders happens to be less than trade within countries, there must be barriers to trade between those countries. Factors that make it easier or more difficult to trade goods between countries are often called border effects, and they include the following: ■Taxes imposed when imported goods enter into a country, tariffs ■ Limits on the number of items allowed to cross the border, quotas ■ Other administrative rules and regulations affecting trade, including the time required for goods to clear customs ■ Geographic factors such as whether the countries share a border ■ Cultural factors such as whether the countries have a common language that might make trade easier Lecture 6, International economics

  41. Conclusions When firms have differentiated products and increasing returns to scale, there is a potential for gains from trade that did not exist in earlier models. The model of monopolistic competition shows that trade will occur between countries even if these countries are identical. There is trade within the same industries across countries because there is a potential to sell in a larger market. This will induce firms to lower their prices below those charged in the absence of trade. As firms exit, remaining firms increase their output and average cost falls. Lower costs results in lower prices for consumers in the importing country. Lecture 6, International economics

  42. Conclusions • Lower prices and higher product variety are the gains from trade under monopolistic competition. • However, since some firms exit the market, there are short-run adjustment costs due to worker displacement. • For a real-life example of these gains and costs, we examined the short-run adjustment costs of NAFTA as well as the long-run gains for the three countries involved. • In the case of intra-industry trade across countries, the question of which countries have a greater tendency to trade with each other turns specially relevant. For this purpose, we examined the gravity equation. • The gravity equation predicts that the larger two countries are, or the closer they are, the greater the amount of trade. Lecture 6, International economics

  43. TIPS for solving problems • Recall that product differentiation alone can give rise to high levels of intra-industry trade. • There are many things at work in trading patterns between countries. • Because different models have different implications, it is important to know which model is appropriate for which phenomenon. Lecture 6, International economics

  44. Lecture 6, International economics

More Related