430 likes | 528 Views
The Growth of Finance, Financial Innovation, and Systemic Risk Lecture 5. BGSE Summer School in Macroeconomics, July 2013 Nicola Gennaioli , Universita ’ Bocconi , IGIER and CREI. Banks and Sovereign Default Risk. Link between government default and private sector turmoil
E N D
The Growth of Finance, Financial Innovation, and Systemic RiskLecture 5 BGSE Summer School in Macroeconomics, July 2013 Nicola Gennaioli, Universita’ Bocconi, IGIER and CREI
Banks and Sovereign Default Risk • Link between government default and private sector turmoil • Russia 1998, but also Pakistan, Ecuador and Argentina (IMF 2002) • European debt crisis: joint fragility of governments and private banks
Government Default and Private Credit • After sovereign default, the flow of private credit comes to a halt
Private credit flow systematically drops after a default episode
The Default-Private Credit Link • Two potential stories for the above correlations: • Greek-style default: financial distress in the government → banks are hurt because they hold government bonds → credit crunch • Irish-style default: private banking crisis → government nationalizes (or bails out) banks → government is over-indebted, twin crisis follows • Can we distinguish between these two views? Do they have different implications?
Upon arrival of bad news, banks holding government bonds suffer…
A First Pass Assessment • Some preliminary support for Greek style default: • financial distress in the government → banks are hurt because they hold government bonds → credit crunch • Irish-style is also important, but let’s start with Greece • A theory of Irish style default should still explain why the government default triggers a sharp credit contraction • Two crucial questions: • If government bonds are deadly, why do banks hold them? • What about the government default decision?
Literature Background (I) • Government default decision: • Traditional literature on sovereign debt (see Eaton and Fernandez 1995)assumes that government defaults can selectively discriminate between foreign and domestic bondholders. • In this theory, the cost of default is external punishment (e.g. exclusion from international financial markets). • In this theory, the government trades off the benefit from defaulting in terms of increasing current consumption, with the cost of being excluded from future borrowing (or trade).
Literature Background (II) • Difficulties with the traditional theory: • Observed exclusion is short lived. To rationalize why countries default so infrequently need output cost (Arellano 2008). • Theoretical problems with the sustainability of penalties • Most important: • In the traditional theory, perfect discrimination implies that banks will be spared from default. That is, when the government defaults, domestic banks will be spared…
Some Observation • Banks exposed to the domestic government are perceived to be in trouble when sovereign debt markets are in strain. • Markets do not expect (perfect) bailouts: • Hard for the government to selectively default, • Hard for the government to finance a bailout during a default episode • We need a theory of Greek-style default
Investment and Default at t = 1 (III) • Let’s step back, for a moment: • - In this theory, the government repays because banks hold public • bonds • - If banks did not hold government bonds, the government would • always default! • - Not necessarily sound to clean up the banking sector from bonds • - Yet, bonds create fragility if a crisis is to occur • What determines banks’ bond-holdings in the first place?
Banks’ Demand for Bonds (II) • Two comments: • - In our model, banks hold government bonds voluntarily, because these bonds allow them to make a carry trade • - In reality, other reasons as well: reserve requirements, central bank lending, financial repression (mostly in developing countries) • Whatever the reason, the story goes through
Debt Sustainability (II) 26 • Debt sustainability requires: • Strong financial institutions: developed private financial markets help the government commit to repay. • This increases the cost for the government of interfering with intermediation • Important role of financial intermediaries (intermediate β): if banks are too small, or if firms can obtain funds at arm’s length, the government has no incentive to save the banking sector
Empirical Predictions • Government default is followed by a drop in private credit. This drop is stronger if: • Banks hold more government bonds • Financial institutions are stronger • Ex-ante probability of default decreases as: • Banks hold more government bonds • Financial institutions are stronger
Data 28
Data (New Paper) • Bank‐level data from BANKSCOPE dataset (Bureau van Dijk): • Provides information on a broad range of bank characteristics • BANKSCOPE suitable for international comparisons because data is harmonized • Crucial: BANKSCOPE reports banks’ holdings of public bonds • However, does not say the nationality of the bonds • We use IMF and EU stress test data to validate this information • Main sample: 4,723 banks in 151 countries; 25,132 bank‐year obs. • Commercial, cooperative and savings banks account for 92% of our sample; investment banks for 1.6%; rest are holdings, real estate, and other credit institutions • Sample construction: start with full data; filter out duplicate records, banks with negative value of assets, banks with total assets < $100,000, years < 1997 when coverage is less systematic. Get: 10,281 banks in 174 countries over 1998‐2010 (58,830 bank‐year observations) • Further impose: two consecutive years of data; data is available on size, leverage, risk taking, profitability, loans, Central Bank balances and other interbank ratios Intro Data Hypotheses and Empirical Strategy Results
Our Tests • Estimate banks’ demand for bondholdings (and of its various components) • Time-invariant (“normal times”) Bondholdings, both at bank and country level • Time-varying (“crisis times”) Bondholdings, both at bank and country level • Estimate effect of bondholdings(and of its various components) on banks’ changes in loans during default • Do banks more exposed to government bonds cut their loans more during default? • Which of the various components of bondholdings demand explain more of this variation? Intro Data Hypotheses and Empirical Strategy Results
Summary of Bondholdings Demand • Normal-time bondholdings account for 80% of total variation of bondholdings in our sample • Largely explained by liquidity/insurance [risk taking (-), leverage (+), fin dev (-)] • Default episodes alone explain 14% of time variation of bonds • Banks take 16% more bonds during default • Huge heterogeneity: esp. larger/more profitable banks load up on government bonds during default • Consistent with risk taking and/or government intervention through moral suasion during crises • Next: do bondholdings affect changes in loans during default? Intro Data Hypotheses and Empirical Strategy Results
Bondholdings and Changes in Loans Intro Data Hypotheses and Empirical Strategy Results
Bottom Line • Powerful feedback effects between banks and sovereign default risk: • A government facing a weak domestic banking sector faces a hard time borrowing, but.. • Financial development will enhance fragility in case of default • Similar to the banking crises studied earlier • Additional implication: a banking crisis can lead to sovereign default risk. Links with Irish-style crises • Banking crisis reduces incentive to repay and tax revenues • Government can try to bail out failed banks
International Contagion • Bolton and Jeanne (2012) use the previous mechanism to generate contagion effects across countries. • International banks hold diversified sovereign bonds portfolios • Default in one country hurts banks in many country • This triggers a recession across countries, in turn increasing the likelihoods of additional government defaults • Ex-ante, countries issue too much debt because they do not internalize the contagion effect on other countries
Irish-style Bailouts • From Acharya, Drechsler and Schanbl (2011) • Imagine that a highly levered banking sector enters a financial crisis. Why would it makes sense for the government to bail it out? • Answer is related to micro-frictions/externalities • This paper: the government might default to relieve the private sector from debt overhang problems • For given taxes, the government dilutes existing government bondholders, reducing the government’s creditowrthiness • This increases the probability of twin defaults when future shocks hit
Correlation between sovereign cds and public debt before and after bailouts