1 / 96

Chapter 11

Chapter 11. Monopoly. Key issues. monopoly profit maximization: MR = MC market power monopoly welfare effects: p > MC  DWL cost advantages that create monopolies government actions that create monopolies government actions that reduce market power

ashling
Download Presentation

Chapter 11

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 11 Monopoly

  2. Key issues • monopoly profit maximization: MR = MC • market power • monopoly welfare effects: p > MC  DWL • cost advantages that create monopolies • government actions that create monopolies • government actions that reduce market power • dominant firm and competitive fringe

  3. Monopoly • monopoly: only supplier of a good for which there is no close substitute • monopoly's output is the market output: q = Q • monopoly's demand curve is market demand curve • its demand curve is downward sloping • it doesn't lose all its sales if its raises its price • it is a price setter

  4. Profit maximization all firms maximize profits by choosing quantity such that marginal revenue = marginal cost MR(Q) = MC(Q)

  5. Marginal revenue • firm's MR curve depends on its demand curve • monopoly's MR curve • lies below its demand curve at any positive quantity • because its demand curve is downward sloping • demand curve shows price, p, it receives for selling a given quantity, Q • price = p = average revenue

  6. Marginal revenue, MR • change in revenue from selling one more unit • MR = R/Q (Calculus: MR = dR(Q)/dQ) • if firm sells exactly one more unit, Q = 1, • its marginal revenue is MR = R • R = R2 – R1 • MR < p at any given Q for a monopoly (but not for a competitive firm)

  7. Figure 11.1a Average and Marginal Revenue R1 = A R2 = A + B (a) Competitive Firm Price, p , R = R2 – R1 = B = p 1 $ per unit Demand curve p 1 A B q q + 1 Quantity, q , Units per year

  8. Figure 11.1b Average and Marginal Revenue (b) Monopoly R1 = A + C R2 = A + B Price, p , $ per unit R = R2 – R1 = B – C = p2 - C p 1 C p 2 Demand curve A B Q Q + 1 Quantity, Q , Units per year

  9. Deriving monopoly’s MR curve • monopoly increases its output by Q, • by lowering its price per unit by p/Q (slope of demand curve) • so monopoly loses (p/Q)Q on units originally sold at higher price: area C • but earns an additional p on extra output: area B • thus: MR = p + (p/Q) Q = p + a negative term < p

  10. Calculus derivation • monopoly’s revenue is R(Q) = p(Q)Q • differentiating with respect to Q: • thus: MR = p + a negative term < p

  11. Figure 11.2 Elasticity of Demand and Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue p , $ per unit Perfectly elastic 24 Elastic, < – 1 e MR = – 2 D p = – 1 D Q = 1 Q = 1 D D = – 1 e 12 Inelastic, – 1 < < 0 e Demand ( p = 24 – Q ) Perfectly inelastic 0 12 24 Q , Units per day MR = 24 – 2 Q

  12. Linear MR curve • for all linear demand curves, p = a - bQ • MR curve is a straight line, MR = a - 2bQ • MR curve hits vertical (price) axis where demand curve does • slope of MR curve = 2  slope of demand curve • MR curve hits horizontal axis at half the quantity as the demand curve

  13. In our example • p = 24 – Q • so a = 24 and b = 1 • p /Q = -1 • henceMR = p + (p/Q) Q = (24 – Q) + (-1)  Q = 24 – 2Q

  14. Using calculus R(Q) = p(Q)Q if linear: R(Q) = [a - bQ]Q = aQ - bQ2 MR = dR/dQ = a - 2bQ

  15. MR andelasticity of demand • MR at any given quantity depends on • demand curve's height (price) • demand curve's shape (elasticity) • thus, it depends on its elasticity

  16. Derive MR/elasticity formula • demand elasticity:  = (Q/Q)/(p/p) = (Q/p)(p/Q) • MR = p + (p/Q) Q = p + (p/Q)(Q/p)p

  17. MR and price • MR • MR closer to p the more elastic is demand • where demand curve hits price axis (Q = 0), demand curve is perfectly elastic  MR = p • MR = 0 where demand elasticity is  = -1 • MR < 0 where demand is inelastic: 0   > -1

  18. Table 11.1 Quantity, Price, Marginal Revenue, and Elasticity for the Linear Inverse Demand Curve p=24-Q

  19. Figure 11.2 Elasticity of Demand and Total, Average, and Marginal Revenue p , $ per unit Perfectly elastic 24 Elastic, < – 1 e MR = – 2 D p = – 1 D Q = 1 Q = 1 D D = – 1 e 12 Inelastic, – 1 < < 0 e Demand ( p = 24 – Q ) Perfectly inelastic 0 12 24 Q , Units per day MR = 24 – 2 Q

  20. Choosing price or quantity • monopoly can set p or Q to maximize its profit,  • monopoly is constrained by market demand curve • it cannot set both Q and p (cannot pick a point above demand curve) • if monopoly sets p, demand curve determines Q • if monopoly sets Q, demand curve determines p • because monopoly wants to maximize , it chooses same profit-maximizing solution whether it sets p or Q

  21. Profit maximization all firms, including monopolies, use a two-step analysis • firm determines output, Q*, at which it makes highest , where • MR = MC • in elastic portion of demand curve 2. firm decides whether to produce Q* or shut down: p  AVC

  22. (a) Monopolized Market Figure 11.3 Maximizing Profit MC p , $ per unit 24 AC AVC e 18 p = 60 12 8 6 Demand MR 0 6 12 24 Q , Units per day (b) Profit, Revenue R , p , $ 144 Revenue, R 108 60 Profit, p 0 6 12 24 , Units per day Q

  23. SR cost in our example • C(Q) = Q2+ 12 • MC = dC(Q)/dQ = 2Q • AVC = VC/Q = Q2/Q = Q • AC = C/Q = (Q2 + 12)/Q = Q + 12/Q

  24. Profit is maximized where • MR = 24 – 2Q = 2Q = MC  Q = 6 • inverse demand: p = 24 – Q = 24 – 6 = 18 • AVC = Q = 6 < p = 18 so produce •  > 0 because AC = Q + 12/Q = 8 < p = 18

  25. Market power ability of a firm to charge a price above marginal cost profitably

  26. No check on bank market power banks exercise substantial market power on the rate for bounced checks • although you had no idea that a check wouldn't clear, bank charges you an average of $4.75 to $7.50 (up to $10) • large banks charge more than small ones • bad check writer also pays an average of $15 to $19.50 (up to $30)

  27. Bank costs • bank's handling fees for bad checks = $1.32 • most checks eventually clear (check writer merely miscalculated balances) • even including losses from fraud, total MC = $2.70 (Center for the Study of Responsive Law) • thus, banks are exercising substantial market power: price > MC

  28. Market power and shape of demand curve • market power depends on shape of demand curve (elasticity) • at profit-maximizing quantity:

  29. Lerner index (price markup) • Lerner index is (p – MC)/p • if firm profit maximizes, • Lerner index ranges from 0 to 1 • p MC • 0  p – MC  p • 0  (p – MC)/p  p/p = 1

  30. Causes of market power monopoly's demand curve is relatively inelastic if • consumers are willing to pay "virtually anything" for it • no close substitutes for firm's product exist • other firms can't enter market • other similar firms are located far away • other firms’ products very different

  31. Welfare effects of monopoly • welfare = consumer surplus + producer surplus • W = CS + PS • welfare is < under monopoly than under competition • monopoly sets p > MC, causing deadweight loss (DWL)

  32. Figure 11.5 Deadweight Loss of Monopoly p , $ per unit 24 MC e m A = $18 C =$ 2 p = 18 m B = $12 e c p = 16 c = $4 E D =$60 MR = MC = 12 Demand MR 0 Q = 6 Q = 8 12 24 m c , Units per day Q

  33. Solved problem • in our linear example, • how does subjecting a monopoly to a specific tax of  = $8 per unit affect • monopoly optimum • welfare of consumers, the monopoly, and society? • what is tax incidence on consumers?

  34. Solved Problem 11.1 p , $ per unit 2 MC (after tax) 24 1 MC (before tax) e A t = $ 8 2 p = 20 2 e B C 1 p = 18 1 E F D 8 G Demand MR 0 Q = 4 Q = 6 12 24 2 1 Q , Units per day

  35. Competitive vs. monopoly sugar tax incidence • incidence of a tax on consumers may be less for a monopolized than a competitive market • in 1996, Florida voted on (and rejected) a one-cents-per-pound excise tax on refined cane sugar in the Florida Everglades Agricultural Area • given linear supply (or marginal cost) and demand curves the tax incidence on consumers from this tax is • 70% if the market is competitive • 41% if monopolistic • thus, a competitive Florida sugar industry passes on substantially more of the tax to demanders than it would if the industry were monopolized

  36. Welfare effects of taxes • governments use ad valorem taxes (p per unit) more often than specific taxes ( per unit) – why? • suppose both taxes cut output by the same amount • which one raises the most government tax revenue?

  37. Figure 11.6 Ad Valorem Versus Specific Tax p , $ per unit e 1 p 2 A e 2 p 1 p = p – t s 2 B p = (1 – ) p a a 2 MC Before-tax demand, D MR s a D D Q Q Q , Units per year s a MR MR 2 1

  38. Why monopolies? • firm has cost advantage over others firms • government created monopoly • merger of several firms into a single firm • firms act collectively: cartel • strategies - such as threats of violence - that discourage other firms from entering market

  39. Sources of cost advantages • firm controls a key input: • essential facility: scarce resource that rival needs to use to survive • firm knows of superior technology, or • has better way of organizing production

  40. Natural monopoly • market has a natural monopoly if one firm can produce total market output at lower cost than could several firms • if cost for Firm i to produces qi is C(qi), condition for a natural monopoly is C(Q) < C(q1) + C(q2) + ... + C(qn), • where Q = q1 + q2 + .. + qn is sum of output of any n > 2 firms

  41. Sufficient condition natural monopoly if • AC curve falls at any observed quantity for all firms • economies of scale

  42. Electricity example • F = $60 (build plant & connect houses) • MC = m = $10 (constant) • AC = m + F/Q = 10 + 60/Q, declines as output rises

  43. Costs of producing Q = 12 • having only one firm produce avoids a • second fixed cost (MC doesn’t vary with • number of firms)

  44. Figure 11.7 Natural Monopoly AC , MC , $ per unit 40 20 = + AC 60/ Q 10 15 10 MC = 10 0 6 12 15 Q, Units per day

  45. Public utilities apparently believing they’re natural monopolies, governments grant monopoly rights for essential good or service “public utilities” • water • gas • electric power • mail delivery

  46. Electric power utilities • AC curve for U.S electric-power-producing firms in 1970 • was U-shaped • reached its minimum at 33 billion kWh per year • whether an electric power utility is a natural monopoly depends on demand it faces

  47. Economies of scale • natural monopolies: most electric companies operated in regions of substantial economies of scale • Newport Electric produced 0.5 billion kWh/year • Iowa Southern Utilities: 1.3 billion kWh/year • not natural monopolies: a few operated in upward-sloping section of AC curve • Southern produced 54 kWh/year • 2 firms could produce that quantity at 3¢ less per thousand kWh than could a single firm

  48. Application Electric Power Utilities Cost, $ per thousand kWh 5.10 D AC 4.85 4.79 0 33 66 Q , Billion kWh per year

  49. Government created monopolies • barriers to entry (e.g, patents) • own and manage many monopolies • postal services • garbage collection • utilities • electricity • water • gas • phone services

More Related