1 / 35

Market structure and competition

Market structure and competition. By A.V. Vedpuriswar. Competitors and Competition A given firm may compete in several input and output markets simultaneously. It is important to analyse each market separately.

Download Presentation

Market structure and competition

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Market structure and competition By A.V. Vedpuriswar

  2. Competitors and Competition • A given firm may compete in several input and output markets simultaneously. • It is important to analyse each market separately. • Two firms directly compete if a price increase by one causes many of its customers to do business with the other. • When firms are direct competitors, the strategic choices of one directly affect the performance of the other. • Products tend to be close substitutes when three conditions hold: • - Same or similar product performance characteristics. • - Same or similar occasions for use. • - Sold in the same geographic market. • The degree to which products substitute each other is measured by the cross price elasticity of demand. • Cross price elasticity = percentage change in demand for good Y • that results from 1% change in the price of X

  3. Market Structure Market structure refers to the number and distribution of firms in a market. We can measure this in many ways. N firm concentration ratio =Combined market share of the N largest firms in the market. Herfindahl index = Sum of the squared market shares of all the firms in the market

  4. Problem The following are the approximate market shares: Coke – 40%, Pepsi – 30%, 7 Up – 10%, Dr Pepper – 10% All other brands – 10% Calculate the Herfindahl index

  5. Herfindahl index = (.4)**2 + (.3)**2 + (.10)**2 + (.10)**2 + (.10)**2 • =.16 + .09 + .01 + .01 + .01 • =0.28

  6. What would happen if Pepsi took over 7 Up?

  7. Herfindahl index =(.4)**2 + (.4)**2 + (.10)**2 + (.10)**2 • = 0.34

  8. Different forms of market structure • Perfect competition • - There are many sellers and well informed buyers. • - Profit is maximised when Price = Marginal cost.

  9. Monopoly • - A firm is a monopolist if it faces little or no competition. • - A monopolist faces a downward sloping demand curve. • - A monopolist selects the price such that marginal revenue equals marginal cost. • - A monopolist can set the price without regard to how other firms will respond.

  10. The monopoly solution (Cont…) price, marginal revenue, marginal cost, average total cost Marginal cost Average total cost E G Marginal revenue Demand Quantity per period

  11. Monopolistic competition • - There are many sellers • - Each seller sells a differentiated product • - A product is vertically differentiated when it is unambiguously better or worse than competing products • - A product is horizontally differentiated when only some consumers prefer it to competing products. • - Horizontal differentiation results when consumers have idiosyncratic preferences.

  12. - Location can be a source of idiosyncratic preferences • - Tastes can be a source of idiosyncratic preferences • - The degree of horizontal differentiation depends on the magnitude of search costs, i.e., how easy or hard it is for customers to get information about alternatives.

  13. Monopolistic competition (short run) MC ATC P Economic profit C D MR Q

  14. Oligopoly • A market in which the actions of individual firms materially affect the industry price level is called Oligopoly. • Each firm has to take into account the strategies of other firms even as it frames its strategy. • Game theory is useful here.

  15. Game theory :Prisoners’ dilemma payoff matrix 3 years 10 years Both admit One denies other admits 1 year 3 years 2 years 1 year One denies, other admits Both deny 10 year 2 years

  16. Game Theory Consider two firms, Alpha and Beta. Each firm must decide whether to increase production capacity in the coming year. The consequences of the firm’s actions are summarised below. Beta Do Not expand Expand Do not expand $18, $18 $ 15, $ 20 Alpha Expand $ 20, $15 $ 16, $ 16

  17. Game Theory (Cont..) Consider pay off for Alpha If Beta expands and Alpha expands, profit = $16 and Alpha does not expand, profit= $ 15 If Beta does not expand and Alpha expands, profit = $20 and Alpha does not expand, profit = $18 So it makes sense for Alpha to expand in both cases. See previous slide

  18. Game Theory (Cont..) Consider pay off for Beta Say Alpha expands Beta does not expand profit = $15 Beta expands profit = $16 Say Alpha does not expand Beta does not expand profit = $18 Beta expands profit = $20 So it makes sense for Beta to expand in both cases See earlier slide

  19. So the Nash equilibrium is that each firm expands its capacity. At the Nash equilibrium, each player is doing the best it can, given the strategies of other players. If each party expects the other to choose its Nash equilibrium strategy, then in fact both parties will choose their Nash equilibrium strategies The Nash equilibrium does not necessarily correspond to the outcome that maximises the aggregate profit of the players.

  20. Beta Do Not Expand Small Large Do Not Expand 18, 18 15, 20 9, 18 Small 20, 15 16, 16 8, 12 Large 18, 9 12, 8 0, 0 Beta Alpha Equilibrium point is Small, Small Alpha

  21. Game Tree for Sequential Capacity Expansion Game If both firms decide simultaneously, the equilibrium is (Small, Small) What happens if Alpha first decides?

  22. In a sequential move game, Alpha’s capacity choice has commitment value. It forces Beta into a corner. By committing to a large capacity expansion, Alpha forces Beta into a position where Beta’s response yields the outcome that is most favourable to alpha. So Alpha makes a large expansion while Beta does not expand. The payoff is (18,9)

  23. Cournot Model • - Consider only two firms in the market. • - They produce identical goods and charge the same prices. • - The sole strategic choice is the total amount they produce, Q1 + Q2 • - The market price is that which enables both firms to sell all their output. • - Each firm’s optimal level of production is the best response to the level it expects its rivals to choose. • This model applies to situations where firms must make production decisions in advance and are committed to selling all their output. • This may be so if bulk of the production costs are sunk or it is costly to hold inventory.

  24. Cournot Equilibrium Suppose there are two players in the market. For A, TC1 = 10 Q1 For B, TC2 = 10 Q2 Marginal cost = ? Market demand is given by Q1+Q2 = 100 – P or P = 100 – (Q1+Q2) At Cournot equilibrium, P1* = 100 – Q1* - Q2* (Q1* , Q2* are market clearing output) Q1* is A’s profit maximising output given that it guesses B will produce Q2* Q2* is B’s profit maximising output given that it guesses A will produce Q1*

  25. Assume that A guesses B will produce Q2g Then A’s profit = Revenues - Total cost = P1 Q1 - 10 Q1 = (100 – Q1-Q2g) Q1 – 10 Q1 = 100 Q1 – Q12 – Q2g Q1 – 10 Q1 Profit = 90 Q1 – Q12 – Q2g Q1 We differentiate and equate to zero to find out maxima/minima. d (profit) / d Q1 = 90 – 2Q1 – Q2g d 2(profit) / dQ12 = -2Q1 = always - ve So it is a maxima point 90 – 2Q1 – Q2g = 0 2Q1 = 90 - Q2g Q1 = 45 - .5 Q2g

  26. So if A expects B to increase its output, it will reduce the output and vice versa. Similarly profit maximising value of Q2 = 45 - .5 Q1g So Q1 = 45 - .5Q2g Q2 = 45 - .5 Q1g At equilibrium, Q2g = 45 - .5 (45 - .5Q2g ) Q2g = 45 – 22.5 + .25 Q2g 0.75 Q2g = 22.5 Q2g = 22.5 /.75 = 30 Q1g = 45 - .5 (30) = 30 So at equilibrium, Q1* = Q2* = 30

  27. Process of adjustment in Carnot equilibrium( Q2 = 45 -0.5*Q1)Q2 ,Q1 are both 40

  28. Bertrand Model • -Each firm selects a price and stands ready to meet all the demand for its products at that price. • -Each firm selects a price to maximise its own profits, given the price that it believes the other firm will select. • -When the firm’s products are perfect substitutes, price competition will be severe. • -Rivalry between the two firms is enough to achieve the perfectly competitive outcome. • -The Bertrand model applies to markets in which capacity is sufficiently flexible so that firms can meet all the demand that arises at the prices they announce. • -Firms expect all increases in sales will come through business stealing.

  29. P = 100 – (Q1 + Q2) Cournot equilibrium is P = 100 – 30 – 30 = 40 But this is not the Bertrand equilibrium. If B charges 40, A may charge 39 and grab the entire market, i.e., Q1 = 100 – P = 61 Profits for A in Cournot equilibrium = (40) (30) – (10) (30) = 900 Profits for B now = (39) (61) – (10) (61) = (29) (61) = 1769

  30. As long as both firms set prices that exceed marginal costs, one firm will have an incentive to undercut the other and grab the entire market. The only possibly equilibrium is P1 = P2 = marginal cost = 10. In Bertrand model, rivalry between the two firms is enough to achieve the perfectly competitive outcome. Price competition will be fierce if the products are perfect substitutes. When products are differentiated, competition will be less intense.

  31. Differences between Cournot and Bertrand model Cournot competitors can be thought of as choosing capacities and then competing as price setters given the capacities chosen earlier. The Cournot model applies most naturally to markets when firms must make production decisions in advance and are committed to selling all of their output. This might occur because the bulk of the production costs are sunk or because it is costly to hold inventory. So prices will adjust more quickly than quantities. Each firm will try to keep sales equal to planned production volumes. Business stealing is not an option.

  32. Bertrand model applies to markets in which capacity is sufficiently flexible. Firms can meet all of the demand that arises at the prices they announce. When products are substitutes, each firm believes it can steal business from its competitors through a small cut in price. Firms expect all the increase in sales to come from business stealing. In equilibrium, margins are driven to zero.

  33. Horizontally differentiated markets Undercutting will not lead to loss of entire business. Say Q1 = 63.42 - 3.08 P1 + 2.25 P2 Q2 = 49.52 – 5.48 P2 + 1.40 P1 A’s Marginal cost = 4.96 B’s Marginal cost = 3.94 A’s profit = (P1 – 4.96) (63.42 – 3.98 P1 + 2.25 P2g) P1 = 10.44 + .2826 P2g B’s profit = (P2g - 3.94) (49.52 – 5.48 P2 + 1.40 P1g) P2 = 6.40 + .1277 P1g Solving P1 = 12.72, P2 = 8.11

  34. (4) Consider a market with two horizontally differentiated firms, X and Y. Each has constant marginal cost of $20. Demand functions are: Qx = 100 – 2 Px + 1 Py Qy = 100 – 2 Py + 1 Px Calculate the Bertrand equilibrium. = (Px – 20) (100 – 2 Px + Pyg) = (Py – 20) (100 – 2 Py + Pxg) Differentiating with respect to P we get, 100 – 4Px + Pyg + 40 = 0 100 – 4Py + Pxg + 40 = 0

  35. At equilibrium, Px = Pxg , Py = Pyg 100 – 4Pxg+ Pyg + 40 = 0 100 – 4Pyg+ Pxg + 40 = 0 Or 400 – 16 Pyg+ 4Pxg + 160 = 0 Adding, we get 500 – 15 Pyg + 200 = 0 Pyg = 700/15, Pxg = 140 + 700/15 = 700/15

More Related