1 / 50

Overview

Overview. Overview. Lesson Overview. Chapter 17 Externalities Optimal Taxes on Consumption Optimal Taxes on Production Optimal Subsidies on Consumption Optimal Subsidies on Production Controversy: The Value of Human Life Summary Review Questions. Optimal Taxes on Consumption.

ginny
Download Presentation

Overview

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Overview Overview BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  2. Lesson Overview Chapter 17 Externalities Optimal Taxes on Consumption Optimal Taxes on Production Optimal Subsidies on Consumption Optimal Subsidies on Production Controversy: The Value of Human Life Summary Review Questions BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  3. Optimal Taxes on Consumption Optimal Taxes on Consumption BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  4. Optimal Taxes on Consumption Introductory Example to Optimal Taxes Suppose cigarettes cost $1.00 to produce each pack, and there are enough competing producers that the no-tax market price equals unit cost, $1.00. Suppose my benefits from smoking are: first pack, $2.30; second, $1.60; third, $1.10; fourth, $0.60; and so on. Suppose your loses from my smoking are $0.40 per pack. Question 1: How many packs do I smoke in the competitive-equilibrium? Is that consumption efficient? (Hint: On the 3rd pack, I gain $0.10 consumer surplus, but you loose $0.40) Question 2: Name a tax on cigarettes that’s so high that the tax equilibrium is inefficient. (Hint: Without tax, on the 1st pack, I gain $1.30 surplus and you loose $0.40.) Question 3: Name a tax on a pack of cigarettes that makes the tax equilibrium efficient. (Hint: Compute efficient # of packs?) BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  5. Optimal Taxes on Consumption The Demand and Supply for CigarettesThe height of the demand curve is the marginal benefit from the last pack of cigarettes. It is the value of cigarettes to the last consumer. For example, the marginal benefit of the 5,000th pack is $10. Equilibrium price $14 Price of a pack of cigarettes 12 A S 10 E 8 6 D = MB 4 2 Equilibrium quantity 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of cigarettes BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  6. Optimal Taxes on Consumption The Demand and Supply for Cigarettes The height of the supply curve is the marginal cost of the last pack of cigarettes. It is the cost of producing to the last producer. For example, the marginal cost of the 5,000th pack is $6. Equilibrium price $14 Price of a pack of cigarettes 12 S = MC 10 E 8 6 D = MB B 4 2 Equilibrium quantity 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of cigarettes BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  7. Optimal Taxes on Consumption A Negative Externality in Consumption can be analyzed by a decrease in the marginal social benefit of consumption below the marginal benefit to consumers. (If a smoker benefits $8.20 and non-smokers lose $4.00, then society as a whole benefits $4.20) $14 MSB curve shifts downward by the amount of the externality --- the marginal external effect Price of a pack of cigarettes 12 S = MC 10 E 8 6 D = MB 4 2 MSB 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of cigarettes BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  8. Optimal Taxes on Consumption Total surplus is maximal (optimal) when marginal social benefit equals marginal cost. A Pigouvian tax on consumers lowers their marginal benefit to equal MSB, and so equilibrium quantity is optimal. $14 Buyers’ price of a pack of cigarettes 12 A S = MC 10 Pigouviantax = $4 per unit 8 6 D = MB B 4 2 MSB 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of cigarettes BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  9. Optimal Taxes on Consumption Optimal (Pigouvian) Taxes on Consumption equal the marginal external effect of the last unit consumed. Without the tax, equilibrium quantity is too high, and it is possible to make everyone better off by reducing consumption. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  10. Optimal Taxes on Production Optimal Taxes on Production BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  11. Optimal Taxes on Production • Pollution is a bad thing. Yet most pollution is a side effect of activities that provide us with good things, such as steel. • Pollution is a side effect of useful activities, so the optimal quantity of pollution isn’t zero. • Then, how much pollution should a societyhave? What are the costs and benefits of pollution? BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  12. Optimal Taxes on Production The Demand and Supply for SteelThe height of the demand curve is the marginal benefit from the last ton of steel. It is the value of steel to the last consumer. For example, the marginal benefit of the 5,000th ton is $100. Equilibrium price $140 Price of a ton of steel 120 A S 100 E 80 60 D = MB 40 20 Equilibrium quantity 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of steel BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  13. Optimal Taxes on Production The Demand and Supply for Cigarettes The height of the supply curve is the marginal cost of the last ton of steel. It is the cost of producing to the last producer. For example, the marginal cost of the 5,000th ton is $60. Equilibrium price $140 Price of a ton of steel 120 S = MC 100 E 80 60 D = MB B 40 20 Equilibrium quantity 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of steel BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  14. Optimal Taxes on Production A Negative Externality in Production can be analyzed by an increase in the marginal social cost of production above the marginal cost to producers. (If producers’ costs are $82 and the environmental costs are $40, then societies’ costs are $122.) $140 MSC Price of a ton of steel 120 S = MC 100 MSC curve shifts upward by the amount of the externality --- the marginal external effect E 80 60 D = MB 40 20 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of steel BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  15. Optimal Taxes on Production Total surplus is maximal (optimal) when marginal benefit equals marginal social cost. A Pigouvian tax on producers raises their marginal cost to equal MSC, and so equilibrium quantity is optimal. $140 MSC Price of a ton of steel 120 A S = MC 100 Pigouviantax = $40 per unit 80 60 D = MB B 40 20 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of steel BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  16. Optimal Taxes on Production Optimal (Pigouvian) Taxes on Production equal the marginal external effect of the last unit produced. Without the tax, equilibrium quantity is too high, and it is possible to make everyone better off by reducing production. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  17. Optimal Subsidies on Consumption Optimal Subsidies on Consumption BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  18. Optimal Subsidies on Consumption The Demand and Supply for Flu ShotsThe height of the demand curve is the marginal benefit from the last flu shot. It is the value of a flu shot to the last consumer. For example, the marginal benefit of the 10,000th shot is $4. Equilibrium price $14 Price of a flu shot 12 S 10 8 6 E A 4 2 D = MB Equilibrium quantity 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of flu shots BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  19. Optimal Subsidies on Consumption The Demand and Supply for Flu ShotsThe height of the supply curve is the marginal cost of the last flu shot. It is the cost of producing to the last producer. For example, the marginal cost of the 10,000th shot is $8. Equilibrium price $14 Price of a flu shot 12 S = MC 10 B 8 6 E 4 2 D = MB Equilibrium quantity 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of flu shots BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  20. Optimal Subsidies on Consumption A Positive Externality in Consumption can be analyzed by an increase in the marginal social benefit of consumption below the marginal benefit to consumers. (If a patient benefits $4.20 and others benefits $4.00, then society as a whole benefits $8.20) $14 MSB curve shifts upward by the amount of the externality --- the marginal external effect Price of a flu shot 12 S = MC 10 8 6 MSB E 4 2 D = MB 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of flu shots BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  21. Optimal Subsidies on Consumption Total surplus is maximal (optimal) when marginal social benefit equals marginal cost. A Pigouvian subsidy on consumers raises their marginal benefit to equal MSB, and so equilibrium quantity is optimal. $14 Buyers’ price of a flu shot 12 S = MC 10 B 8 Pigouvian subsidy = $4 per unit 6 D = MB A 4 2 MSB 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of flu shots BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  22. Optimal Subsidies on Consumption Optimal (Pigouvian) Subsidies on Consumption equal the marginal external effect of the last unit consumed. Without the tax, equilibrium quantity is too low, and it is possible to make everyone better off by increasing consumption. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  23. Optimal Subsidies on Production Optimal Subsidies on Production BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  24. Optimal Subsidies on Production The Demand and Supply for HoneyThe height of the demand curve is the marginal benefit from the last case of honey. It is the value of honey to the last consumer. For example, the marginal benefit of the 10,000th case is $80. Equilibrium price $140 S Price of a case of honey 120 E 100 A 80 Equilibrium quantity 60 D = MB 40 20 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of honey BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  25. Optimal Subsidies on Production The Demand and Supply for Cigarettes The height of the supply curve is the marginal cost of the last ton of steel. It is the cost of producing to the last producer. For example, the marginal cost of the 10,000th case is $120. Equilibrium price $140 S = MC Price of a case of honey B 120 E 100 80 Equilibrium quantity 60 D = MB 40 20 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of honey BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  26. Optimal Subsidies on Production A Positive Externality in Production can be analyzed by an decrease in the marginal social cost of production below the marginal cost to producers. (If producers’ costs are $122 and the environmental benefits to plants are $40, then societies’ costs are $82.) $140 S = MC Price of a case of honey 120 E MSC 100 MSC curve shifts downward by the amount of the externality --- the marginal external effect 80 60 D = MB 40 20 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of honey BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  27. Optimal Subsidies on Production Total surplus is maximal (optimal) when marginal benefit equals marginal social cost. A Pigouvian tax on producers lowers their marginal cost to equal MSC, and so equilibrium quantity is optimal. $140 S = MC Price of a case of honey B 120 Pigouvian subsidy = $40 per unit MSC 100 A 80 60 D = MB 40 20 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 Quantity of honey BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  28. Optimal Subsidies on Production Optimal (Pigouvian) Subsidies on Production equal the marginal external effect of the last unit produced. Without the subsidy, equilibrium quantity is too lower, and it is possible to make everyone better off by increasing production. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  29. Controversy: Value of Human Life Controversy: Value of Human Life BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  30. Controversy: Welfare There are several practical problems to overcome when measuring the harmful marginal external effect of negative externalities like smoking cigarettes or producing pollution. If, say, the last cigarette pack increased by 0.00001% the chance of people near you dying of cancer, you must place a dollar value on their lives to determine the optimal tax. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  31. Controversy: Welfare What is the dollar value of someone's life? Is it infinity? --- as Catholics and lawyers tell us. Maybe they are right, but as economists we work under the assumption of rationality. Someone's life has the same value that they place on it. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  32. Controversy: Welfare For example, suppose that by inspecting your roof yourself, rather than having someone else do it for you, you save $20, but increase your chance of death (by falling) by 0.0001%. Consider these implications: Since rich people do not find $20 enough incentive to inspect their own roofs, the value of their lives is more than $20. Since poor people do find $20 enough incentive to inspect their own roofs, the value of their lives is less than $20. In particular, the cost of risking a rich person's life is greater than the cost of risking a poor person's life. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  33. Controversy: Welfare • The optimal tax on various negative externalities is affected by the difference in cost of risking a rich person's life and risking a poor person's life: • Drunk and reckless driving and speeding should be more heavily enforced and punished in rich neighborhoods. • Dumping toxic waste should be more heavily restricted and punished in rich neighborhoods. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  34. Summary Summary BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  35. Review Questions • Review Questions • You should try to answer some of the following questions before the next class. • You will not turn in your answers, but students may request to discuss their answers to begin the next class. • Your upcoming cumulative Final Exam will contain some similar questions, so you should eventually consider every review question before taking your exam. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  36. Review Questions Follow the link http://faculty.pepperdine.edu/jburke2/ba210/PowerP3/Set11Answers.pdf for review questions for Lesson III.4 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  37. Review Questions Review Question 1 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  38. Review Questions Question 1. To understand how to promote social behavior, consider the lifetime demand for flu shots by a typical (selfish) person: Suppose the marginal cost of producing flu shots is $1.20 per shot. Suppose that each person has 2 co-workers, and each benefits by $0.10 for each shot the person takes. If the government imposes the optimal subsidy, how many shots does each person take? BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  39. Review Questions Answer 1. Since shots are an example of a positive consumption externality, use this formula: (Optimal subsidy) = (marginal external effect on everyone else). Hence, given the data, (Efficient subsidy) = 2 × 0.10 = 0.20 Hence, the buyer’s price falls from 1.20 to 1.20−.20 = 1.00. Conclusion: Reading from the demand curve, 5 shots are taken by each person. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  40. Review Questions Review Question 2 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  41. Review Questions Question 2. To understand how to control anti-social behavior, consider a world with 6 people: 1 drinks and drives, 5 do not drink. Here is the demand for shots of whisky by the drinker. Suppose each of the 5 drink-haters loses $0.05 of happiness for each pint the drinker drinks. (The cost includes the chance of being killed by the drunk driver.) Suppose the unit cost of producing whisky is $0.40 per shot, and the market is perfectly competitive. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  42. Review Questions Assuming there are no taxes or subsidies, compute total surplus. Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax, compute the number of shots of whisky that are drunk. Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax, then compute total surplus. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  43. Review Questions Answer 2. Since the market is perfectly competitive, the sellers’ price of whisky is $0.40 per shot. Assuming there are no taxes or subsidies, consumption = 6, producer surplus = 0, consumer surplus = 1.00+0.90+0.80+0.60+0.30+0.00 minus 5x0.05x6 = $2.10, So total surplus is $2.10 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  44. Review Questions Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax = marginal external effect = 5x0.05 per shot, the buyers’ price of whisky is 0.40+0.25 = $0.65 per shot, so 5 shots of whisky are drunk. Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax, consumption = 5, producer surplus = 0, consumer surplus = 0.75+0.65+0.55+0.35+0.05 = $2.35, Since the tax revenue balances the external effect, the optimal tax increased total surplus to $2.35 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  45. Review Questions Review Question 3 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  46. Review Questions Question 3. To understand how to control anti-social behavior, consider a world with 9 people: 1 smokes, 3 do not care about smoke, 5 hate the smell of smoke. Here is the demand for cigarettes by the smoker. Suppose each of the 5 smoke-haters loses $0.10 of happiness for each pack the smoker smokes.(The cost includes the chance of dying from second-hand smoke.) Suppose the unit cost of producing cigarettes is $0.20 per pack, and the market is perfectly competitive. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  47. Review Questions Assuming there are no taxes or subsidies, compute total surplus. Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax, compute the number of shots of whisky that are drunk. Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax, then compute total surplus. BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  48. Review Questions Answer 2. Since the market is perfectly competitive, the sellers’ price of cigarettes is $0.20 per pack. Assuming there are no taxes or subsidies, consumption = 7, producer surplus = 0, consumer surplus = 1.20+1.10+1.00+0.80+0.50+0.20+0.00 - 5x0.10x7 = $1.30, So total surplus is $1.30 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  49. Review Questions Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax = marginal external effect = 5x0.10 per pack, the buyers’ price of cigarettes is 0.20+0.70 = $0.70 per pack, so 5 packs are smoked. Assuming the government imposes the optimal tax, consumption = 5, producer surplus = 0, consumer surplus = 0.70+0.60+0.50+0.30+0.00 = $2.10, Since the tax revenue balances the external effect, the optimal tax increased total surplus to $2.10 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

  50. BA 210 Introduction to Microeconomics End of Lesson III.4 BA 210 Lesson III.4 Externalities

More Related