310 likes | 535 Views
Healthcare Innovation in the US: A Theoretical Problem in Search of an Empirical Solution. John A. Nyman Health Policy and Management University of Minnesota. Overview. Asked to discuss the economist’s perspective on healthcare innovation Economists interested in incentives
E N D
Healthcare Innovation in the US: A Theoretical Problem in Search of an Empirical Solution John A. Nyman Health Policy and Management University of Minnesota Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Overview • Asked to discuss the economist’s perspective on healthcare innovation • Economists interested in incentives • Health economists have (at least) 3 views of incentives surrounding healthcare innovation • Innovation incentives are derived from insurance and represent dynamic moral hazard • Innovation incentives are derived from market competition and represent cost-reducing efficiency • Innovation incentives are derived from government granting monopoly power through patents Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Innovation as Dynamic Moral Hazard • For the last 30 years or so, most US health economists have held that the main motivation for additional health care spending in the US is health insurance • Theory suggested that when consumers become insured, they face a reduced price for health care and consume more healthcare as a result • The additional care is called “moral hazard” and it is assumed to be care of relatively low value to consumers • But the costs of producing the care remain high, so an inefficiency or welfare loss obtains • Mark V. Pauly “The Economics of Moral Hazard,” Am Econ Rev, 1968 Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Moral Hazard Welfare Loss $/M Demand for medical care P = Marginal Cost P0 = WTP M0 M (medical care) Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Moral Hazard Welfare Loss $/M Demand for medical care A B P = Marginal Cost P = MC P = 0 M (medical care) Mu Mi Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Moral Hazard Welfare Loss $/M Moral Hazard Welfare Loss—An Inefficiency Demand for medical care A B P = the marginal cost of producing a unit of medical care P = MC P = 0 M (medical care) Mu Mi Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Dynamic Moral Hazard • Because insurance stands ready to pay for any health care consumed, insurance also represents an incentive to develop new health care technologies • According to the conventional model, innovation therefore consists of new healthcare technologies that improve health but only marginally, and at a production cost that is too great • This is referred to as dynamic moral hazard • Thus, many US health economists view insurance as providing an incentive for inefficient innovation in health care Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
New Theory • I have suggested that this theory is wrong • John A. Nyman, The Theory of Demand for Health Insurance, Stanford U Press, 2003 • My new theory is based on the simple idea that the price decrease in insurance is largely effective only for those who are ill • For example, what healthy consumer would purchase a coronary bypass procedure (or organ transplant or course of chemotherapy) just because he was insured and the price he faced had dropped to zero Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
New Theory • So, the price reduction in insurance is largely only effective for those who are ill and represents the vehicle by which income is transferred from the healthy to the ill • That is, this price reduction creates access to health care • If insurance actually paid off with this income transfer, say, by writing a check upon diagnosis to the consumer for the average cost his or her care, the consumer would be able to show his or her increased willingness to pay for the additional health care • Therefore, a large portion of moral hazard is actually efficient Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Moral Hazard Under New Theory $/M Di Original demand curve with willingness to pay based on original income C Du B P = MC A New demand curve with the higher willingness to pay from the additional income that is transferred by insurance P = 0 M (medical care) Mu Mi Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Moral Hazard Can Increase Consumer Surplus $/M Di Consumer Surplus— An Efficiency Du B P = Marginal Cost P = MC A P = 0 M (medical care) Mu Mi Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Conclusion for Moral Hazard • Therefore, the welfare consequences of moral hazard (including dynamic moral hazard) are not known theoretically, but must be determined empirically • Cost-benefit analysis can answer that question because CBA seeks to determine whether the consumer’s willingness-to-pay for medical care exceeds the cost of producing it • If WTP > cost, then the additional medical care is efficient, even though the medical care is purchased by the consumer because of insurance Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Conclusion for Dynamic Moral Hazard • In the same way, cost-benefit analysis (CBA) can be used to determine whether a new technology is efficient • Any new technology that is generated by insurance incentives, but that passes the CBA test (WTP > Cost), is efficient • So, insurance incentives for innovation are good as long as they produce new technologies that pass a cost-benefit standard Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Innovation as Competitive Efficiency • More recently, health economists in the US have begun to consider innovation as a means for reducing costs • That is, rather than producing a new technology that increases costs but achieves better health at the same time, • This argument says that innovation can represent a new technology that lowers costs for the same gain in health Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Innovation as Competitive Efficiency • The impetus for innovation is profit-seeking firms in a competitive healthcare market environment • Profit-seeking firms—health plans, physician clinics, hospitals (even though they are non-profit) desire to reduce costs to increase profits (or hospital surpluses) • Competition from other firms requires that firms continually adopt cost-saving innovations or lose business to other firms Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Innovation as Competitive Efficiency • There is some confusion regarding the type of evidence that would support this view • Some of the evidence that is cited in the literature is actually no different than the cost-benefit analysis (CBA) standard just described, because the authors evaluate the health care results in the same way that health benefits are determined in CBA • Cutler, McClellan, Newhouse, Remler. “Are Medical Prices Declining? Evidence from Heart Attacks” (Quart J Econ, 1998) • David Cutler, Your Money or Your Life (Oxford University Press, 2004) Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Innovation as Competitive Efficiency • The true empirical evidence to support this argument, however, should simply demonstrate declining costs from an innovative technology • Thus, rather than a cost-benefit analysis (CBA), a simple cost analysis or cost-focused return on investment (ROI) analysis should be the empirical test • For example, a new treatment for diabetes patients might cost $30,000 but if it resulted in reduced diabetes maintenance costs by, say, $60,000, it would generate a $30,000 net cost savings • Applies to only a small portion of technologies Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Government Granting of Patent Monopoly • The third major perspective of US economists is that innovation incentives derive from the desire of firms to obtain the monopoly profits associated with a patent monopoly • The argument supporting patents is that research and development (R&D) is costly • Often because of the regulatory requirements for safety established by the government • In a competitive economy, innovation might initially generate high profits, but they exist only temporarily until competitors figure out how to make and sell the new product Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Government Granting of Patent Monopoly • The second firm to produce the new technology has a cost advantage because it did not incur the R&D costs associated with innovation • Therefore, the second firm in the market (and subsequent producers) can profitably sell the innovation at a lower price than the innovator • Thus, the innovator has only a limited natural window for exercising monopoly pricing to recoup the R&D expenses • The limitedness of this window and cost disadvantage vis a vis competing firms would act to reduce the amount of innovation Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Government Granting of Patent Monopoly • In order to encourage innovation, government steps in and grants a patent monopoly • The patent prohibits competitors from producing and selling the new technology and gives the innovator a longer period of monopoly pricing with which to recoup the R&D costs of the new technology • Thus, patents create a larger incentive to innovate by enabling innovators to recoup R&D costs and make additional profits from the new technology Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Government Granting of Patent Monopoly • But it is not clear what the optimal level of patent life or profits should be • For example in the pharmaceutical industry, some think that patent lives and drug profits are too high • Marcia Angell, The Truth About Drug Companies, Random House, 2004 • Others think that they are too low • There is no standard regarding what is the level of patent protection and profitability that would encourage the optimal amount of innovation Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Government Granting of Patent Monopoly • Philipson and Jena note that (other than patents) the de facto standard that regulates the amount of innovation is cost-benefit analysis • (Philipson and Jena, “Surplus Appropriation from R&D and Health Care Technology Assessment Procedures,” iHEA Conference, 2007) • But cost-benefit analysis is based on the consumer’s surplus • that is, difference between the consumer’s willingness to pay and the price of the new technology Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Government Granting of Patent Monopoly • This might be ok for determining the value of new technologies once they have been produced • But, Jena and Philipson note that the firm’s decision to innovate under a patent model is instead based on the producer’s surplus • that is, the difference between the price the firm receives and the cost of developing and producing the innovation • The influence of CBA on firm behavior is not related to the producer’s surplus Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Supply and Demand in the Market for Innovations $/M Supply (marginal cost of new product for firms) Demand (willingness to pay of consumers for new product) M (innovative medical care) Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Consumer Surplus v.Producer Surplus $/M Supply (firm’s marginal cost of producing innovation) Market price occurs where supply= demand Pe Demand (willingness to pay of consumers for new product) M (innovative medical care) Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Consumer Surplus v.Producer Surplus $/M Existing CBA standard is based on consumer surplus Supply (firm’s marginal cost of producing innovation) Pe Demand (willingness to pay of consumers for new product) M (innovative medical care) Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Consumer Surplus v.Producer Surplus $/M Existing CBA standard is based on consumer surplus Supply (firm’s marginal cost of producing innovation) Pe Firm’s actual incentive to innovate is based instead on producer’s surplus Demand (willingness to pay of consumers for new product) M (innovative medical care) Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
CBA and Innovation • Thus, CBA is the correct measure for determining whether a new technology is socially efficient once it has been developed • But, it is the wrong measure to use as an incentive to encourage firms to innovate • Indeed, Jena and Philipson claim that a CBA standard acts to reduce innovations compared to a profit-based criterion • This is because an innovation with a lower acquisition price is more likely to pass the CBA standard, but a lower acquisition price means that the new technology is less likely to exist in the first place Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Conclusions • Three perspectives of economists • Incentives to innovate stem from • insurance and represent dynamic moral hazard, conventionally an incentive for inefficient innovation but in actuality it could be efficient • profit-maximizing firms in competitive markets, and represent an incentive for efficient innovation • government patent monopolies that produce innovation of unknown efficiency • No one has determined what the optimal patent protection means Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota
Conclusions • CBA is the standard for determining whether a cost-increasing technology is worth it once it has been developed • But while CBA can correctly evaluate the social net value of existing new technologies, • It probably does not represent the correct empirical test for achieving the optimal amount of innovation • In fact, it may result in a disincentive to innovate, compared to the optimum Healthcare and Innovation, University of Minnesota