1 / 18

Maximization without Calculus

Maximization without Calculus. Not all economic maximization problems can be solved using calculus If a manager does not know the profit function, but can approximate parts of it by straight lines. . d  /d q does not exist at q *. *.  = f ( q ). Quantity. q*.

jesus
Download Presentation

Maximization without Calculus

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Maximization without Calculus • Not all economic maximization problems can be solved using calculus • If a manager does not know the profit function, but can approximate parts of it by straight lines  d/dq does not exist at q* *  = f(q) Quantity q*

  2. Maximization without Calculus • Calculus also cannot be used in the case where a firm cannot produce fractional values of output • d/dq does not exist at q*

  3. Second Order Conditions - Functions of One Variable • Let y = f(x) • A necessary condition for a maximum is that dy/dx = f ’(x) = 0 • To ensure that the point is a maximum, y must be decreasing for movements away from it

  4. Second Order Conditions - Functions of One Variable • The total differential measures the change in y dy = f ‘(x) dx • To be at a maximum, dy must be decreasing for small increases in x • To see the changes in dy, we must use the second derivative of y

  5. Second Order Conditions - Functions of One Variable • Note that d 2y < 0 implies that f ’’(x)dx2 < 0 • Since dx2 must be positive, f ’’(x) < 0 • This means that the function f must have a concave shape at the critical point

  6. Second Order Conditions - Functions of Two Variables • Suppose that y = f(x1, x2) • First order conditions for a maximum are y/x1 = f1 = 0 y/x2 = f2 = 0 • To ensure that the point is a maximum, y must diminish for movements in any direction away from the critical point

  7. Second Order Conditions - Functions of Two Variables • The slope in the x1 direction (f1) must be diminishing at the critical point • The slope in the x2 direction (f2) must be diminishing at the critical point • But, conditions must also be placed on the cross-partial derivative (f12 = f21) to ensure that dy is decreasing for all movements through the critical point

  8. Second Order Conditions - Functions of Two Variables • The total differential of y is given by dy = f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 • The differential of that function is d 2y = (f11dx1 + f12dx2)dx1 + (f21dx1 + f22dx2)dx2 d 2y = f11dx12 + f12dx2dx1 + f21dx1 dx2 + f22dx22 • By Young’s theorem, f12 = f21 and d 2y = f11dx12 + 2f12dx2dx1 + f22dx22

  9. Second Order Conditions - Functions of Two Variables d 2y = f11dx12 + 2f12dx2dx1 + f22dx22 • For this equation to be unambiguously negative for any change in the x’s, f11 and f22 must be negative • If dx2 = 0, then d 2y = f11dx12 • For d 2y < 0, f11 < 0 • If dx1 = 0, then d 2y = f22dx22 • For d 2y < 0, f22 < 0

  10. Second Order Conditions - Functions of Two Variables d 2y = f11dx12 + 2f12dx2dx1 + f22dx22 • If neither dx1 nor dx2 is zero, then d 2y will be unambiguously negative only if f11 f22 - f122 > 0 • The second partial derivatives (f11 and f22) must be sufficiently large that they outweigh any possible perverse effects from the cross-partial derivatives (f12 = f21)

  11. Constrained Maximization • Suppose we want to choose x1 and x2 to maximize y = f(x1, x2) • subject to the linear constraint c - b1x1 - b2x2 = 0 • We can set up the Lagrangian L = f(x1, x2) - (c - b1x1 - b2x2)

  12. Constrained Maximization • The first-order conditions are f1 - b1 = 0 f2 - b2 = 0 c - b1x1 - b2x2 = 0 • To ensure we have a maximum, we must use the “second” total differential d 2y = f11dx12 + 2f12dx2dx1 + f22dx22

  13. Constrained Maximization • Only the values of x1 and x2 that satisfy the constraint can be considered valid alternatives to the critical point • Thus, we must calculate the total differential of the constraint -b1dx1 - b2dx2 = 0 dx2 = -(b1/b2)dx1 • These are the allowable relative changes in x1 and x2

  14. Constrained Maximization • Because the first-order conditions imply that f1/f2 = b1/b2, we can substitute and get dx2 = -(f1/f2) dx1 • Since d 2y = f11dx12 + 2f12dx2dx1 + f22dx22 we can substitute for dx2 and get d 2y = f11dx12 - 2f12(f1/f2)dx1 + f22(f12/f22)dx12

  15. Constrained Maximization • Combining terms and rearranging d 2y = f11 f22- 2f12f1f2 + f22f12 [dx12/ f22] • Therefore, for d 2y < 0, it must be true that f11 f22- 2f12f1f2 + f22f12 < 0 • This equation characterizes a set of functions termed quasi-concave functions • Any two points within the set can be joined by a line contained completely in the set

  16. Constrained Maximization • Recall the fence problem: Maximize A = f(x,y) = xy subject to the constraint P - 2x - 2y = 0 • Setting up the Lagrangian [L = x·y + (P - 2x - 2y)] yields the following first-order conditions: L/x = y - 2 = 0 L/y = x - 2 = 0 L/ = P - 2x - 2y = 0

  17. Constrained Maximization • Solving for the optimal values of x, y, and  yields x = y = P/4 and  = P/8 • To examine the second-order conditions, we compute f1 = fx= y f2 = fy = x f11 = fxx = 0 f12 = fxy = 1 f22 = fyy = 0

  18. Constrained Maximization • Substituting into f11 f22- 2f12f1f2 + f22f12 we get 0 ·x2 - 2 ·1 ·y ·x + 0 ·y2 = -2xy • Since x and y are both positive in this problem, the second-order conditions are satisfied

More Related