1 / 33

The Social Benefits of Higher Education

The Social Benefits of Higher Education. David Bloom, Matthew Hartley, and Henry Rosovsky March 4, 2004. State Spending Per Higher Education Student (in real 2002 dollars).

Download Presentation

The Social Benefits of Higher Education

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Social Benefits of Higher Education David Bloom, Matthew Hartley, and Henry Rosovsky March 4, 2004

  2. State Spending Per Higher Education Student(in real 2002 dollars) Source: Websites of Chronicle of Higher Education and National Center for Education Statistics; student numbers in 1994, 2001, and 2002 are estimates.

  3. The Array of Higher Education Benefits Public Private • Increased Tax Revenues • Greater Productivity • Increased Consumption • Increased Workforce Flexibility • Decreased Reliance on Government Financial Support • Higher Salaries and Benefits • Employment • Higher Savings Levels • Improved Working Conditions • Personal/Professional Mobility Economic • Reduced Crime Rates • Increased Charitable Giving/Community Service • Increased Quality of Civic Life • Social Cohesion/Appreciation of Diversity • Improved Ability to Adapt to and Use Technology • Improved Health/Life Expectancy • Improved Quality of Life for Offspring • Better Consumer Decision Making • Increased Personal Status • More Hobbies, Leisure Activities Social Source: The Institute for Higher Education Policy, “Reaping the Benefits: Defining the Public and Private Value of Going to College”, March 1998.

  4. Rate of Return • A formal way to compare the immediate costs and the subsequent benefits of investment in schooling. • The costs include tuition and fees and the income forgone while in school. • The benefits include the higher earnings that individuals expect to earn as a result of schooling.

  5. Private vs. social, in practice • The private rate of return reflects the direct cost of schooling to individuals (i.e., their out-of-pocket cost). • The social rate of return reflects the full cost to society of schooling, including any public subsidies. • The private rate of return should be based on after-tax income, whereas the social rate of return should be based on pre-tax income, but this is not always done.

  6. Typical Estimates of Returns to Education, based on 98 country studies during 1960-1997(“The classic pattern of falling returns to education by level of … education are maintained.”) Source: G. Psacharopoulos and H. Pastrinos, “Returns to Investment in Education: A Further Update”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2881, September 2002 (from Table 1).

  7. Inferences and concerns…. (from Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2002) “Private returns are higher than social returns where the latter is defined on the basis of private benefits but total (private plus external) costs. This is because of the public subsidization of education and the fact that typical social rate of return estimates are not able to include social benefits. Nevertheless, the degree of public subsidization increases with the level of education, which has regressive income distribution implications.” “There is a concern in the literature with what might be called “social” rates of return that include true social benefits, or externalities…. If one could include externalities, then social rates of return may well be higher than private rates of return to education.”

  8. Constructing Estimates of Private and Social Rates of Return to Education • Requires data/assumptions about the lifetime earnings trajectories of individuals with different amounts of schooling. • Requires data/assumptions about the out-of-pocket costs of schooling to individuals and to society. • Requires data/assumptions about any income spillovers that result from one worker’s education.

  9. Simulation Assumptions • Worker’s earnings with no schooling: $40,000 per year, age 20 through 60 • Worker’s earnings with 1 year of additional schooling: $44,000 per year, age 20 through 60 • Private cost of 1 yr of schooling: $5,000 • Social cost of 1 yr of schooling: $20,000 • Number of workers whose earnings are increased due to one worker’s schooling increasing by 1 year: $1,000 • Amount by which their earnings are increased: $2 per year

  10. Lifetime Earnings Trajectory: Effect of One Year of Schooling 44,000 40,000 Worker’s increased earnings Annual income Foregone income 0 Age: 20 21 30 40 50 60

  11. Lifetime Earnings Trajectory: Effect of One Year of Schooling,With Direct Costs 44,000 40,000 Worker’s increased earnings Annual income Foregone income 0 -5,000 Age: 20 21 30 40 50 60

  12. Lifetime Earnings Trajectory: Effect of One Year of Schooling,With Social Costs 44,000 40,000 Worker’s increased earnings Annual income Foregone income -20,000 Age: 20 21 30 40 50 60

  13. Lifetime Earnings Trajectory: Effect of One Year of Schooling,With Social Costs and Income Spillovers 46,000 44,000 40,000 Worker’s increased earnings Income spillovers Annual income Foregone income -20,000 Age: 20 21 30 40 50 60

  14. No schooling cost 8.5 Private schooling cost = $5,000 8.3 Social schooling cost = $20,000 8.0 Social schooling cost, and income spillover of $2,000 14.3 Simulated Rates of Return

  15. Estimates of the rate of return to schooling in the US, by gender,1962 and 1963-2003(based on standard human capital earnings functions fit to Current Population Survey data)

  16. Notes on estimates of the rate of return to schooling in the US In keeping with standard practice among labor economists, the rate of return to schooling is estimated as the coefficient on years of schooling in an ordinary least squares regression in which the dependent variable is the natural logarithm of the previous years' annual earnings. In addition to years of schooling, the regressors include years of potential work experience (defined as age minus years of schooling minus 6) and its square, and dummy variables for nonwhites and for currently married individuals. Rate of return estimates were constructed separately for males and females for 1962, and for each year during 1964-2003. (The education variable is not usable for 1963.) The data are restricted to individuals aged 20-64 who were employed full time (35 or more hours per week) and year round (50-52 weeks per year). Top-coded earnings figures are adjusted upward by 15 percent of the relevant top code. In addition, we follow the algorithm proposed by Jaeger (1997) for dealing with the change in the CPS education variable that was initiated in 1992 (David A. Jaeger. "Reconciling the old and new census bureau education questions: recommendations for researchers." Journal of Business & Economic Statistics. July 1997. Vol. 15, No. 3). The rate of return estimates may be interpreted as the percentage increase in wages that is associated, cet. par., with each additional year of schooling.

  17. Some limitations of the human capital approach • Evidence of a causal link that runs from schooling to income • Narrow conception of the benefits of schooling • Neglects the effect of schooling on an individual’s welfare, above and beyond any increment to their earnings • Neglects the effect of schooling on social welfare, beyond the income gains to the individuals who receive the schooling

  18. Higher Education and Good Governance(cross-country correlations with tertiary enrollment rates; all governance indicators are scored on 6 or 10 point scales with higher values reflecting better ratings) Source of governance data: International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) data, as compiled and processed by Stephen Knack and the University of Maryland.

  19. Variable Definitions(Source: International Country Risk Guide) • Corruption in Government -- Lower scores indicate "high government officials are likely to demand special payments" and that "illegal payments are generally expected throughout lower levels of government" in the form of "bribes connected with import and export licenses, exchange controls, tax assessment, police protection, or loans." • Rule of Law -- This variable "reflects the degree to which the citizens of a country are willing to accept the established institutions to make and implement laws and adjudicate disputes." Higher scores indicate: "sound political institutions, a strong court system, and provisions for an orderly succession of power." Lower scores indicate: "a tradition of depending on physical force or illegal means to settle claims." Upon changes in government new leaders "may be less likely to accept the obligations of the previous regime." • Quality of the Bureaucracy -- High scores indicate "an established mechanism for recruitment and training," "autonomy from political pressure," and "strength and expertise to govern without drastic changes in policy or interruptions in government services" when governments change. • Ethnic Tensions -- This variable “measures the degree of tension within a country attributable to racial, nationality, or language divisions. Lower ratings are given to countries where racial and nationality tensions are high because opposing groups are intolerant and unwilling to compromise. Higher ratings are given to countries where tensions are minimal, even though such differences may still exist.” • Risk of Repudiation of Contracts by Government -- This indicator addresses the possibility that foreign businesses, contractors, and consultants face the risk of a modification in a contract taking the form of a repudiation, postponement, or scaling down" due to "an income drop, budget cutbacks, indigenization pressure, a change in government, or a change in government economic and social priorities." Lower scores signify "a greater likelihood that a country will modify or repudiate a contract with a foreign business." • Risk of Expropriation of Private Investment -- This variables evaluates the risk "outright confiscation and forced nationalization" of property. Lower ratings "are given to countries where expropriation of private foreign investment is a likely event."

  20. Higher Education andEntrepreneurial Activity • The Total Entrepreneurship Activity (TEA) Index represents represents the share of adults involved in new firms or start-up activities. • Individuals with higher levels of education have higher levels of entrepreneurial activity. • This result holds true in a large number of countries (though the data almost entirely cover only developed countries).

  21. Proportion of WWII veterans among men by age in 1964 (Source: tabulated from the Current Population Survey)

  22. Proportion of Korean War veterans among men by age in 1964(Source: tabulated from the Current Population Survey)

  23. Proportion of men with college or higher degrees by age in 1964(Source: tabulated from the Current Population Survey)

  24. Proportion of men and women with college or higher degrees by age in 1964(Source: tabulated from the March 1964 Current Population Survey)

  25. Income Spillovers Analysis Study of earnings variation among US workers who are (statistically) comparable in terms of their: • Educational attainment • Years of work experience • Gender • Race • Marital status • Industry • Occupation • State of residence • Full-time, year-round status

  26. Main Result of the Income Spillovers Analysis • Other things equal, workers earn more when they are located in states that have higher proportions of college graduates. • Thus, not only do college graduates have relatively high productivity and earnings, they also appear to enhance the productivity and earnings of those with whom they work.

  27. Income Spillovers Analysis -- Descriptive Statistics NOTE: All observations have been drawn from the 1982, 1992, and 2002 March CPS. Sample includes full-time workers between the ages of 18 and 64. Weekly earnings are in 2002 current dollars, deflated by the CPI.

  28. Industry Categories 1 "Agriculture & Forestry" 2 "Mining" 3 "Construction" 4 "Manufacturing-Durables" 5 "Manufacturing-Nondurables" 6 "Transportation" 7 "Communication" 8 "Utilities" 9 "Wholesale Trade" 10 "Retail Trade" 11 "Finance, Insurance & Real Estate" 12 "Private Household Service" 13 "Business & Repair" 14 "Personal Service" 15 "Entertainment Service" 16 "Professional Service" 17 "Public Administration" Occupation Categories 1 "Managers & Administrators" 2 "Professional & Technical" 3 "Sales" 4 "Clerical" 5 "Private Household Service" 6 "Service exc Private Household Service" 7 "Craftsmen" 8 "Operatives exc Transport" 9 "Transport Equipment Operatives" 10 "Laborers" 11 "Farmers" Industry and Occupation Categories

  29. Income Spillovers Analysis: Log Wage Regression Results with Percentage with College or Higher Degrees by State, Whole SampleDependent variable: log (weekly earnings). NOTE: All reported regressions also include the following independent variables: age and its square, three race/ethnic dummies, a marriage dummy, a female dummy, and two year dummies. Standard errors are in parentheses. Columns 4 and 6 include fifty state dummies. Columns 5 and 6 include 16 industry and 10 occupation dummies. * Statistically significant at the .10 level. ** Statistically significant at the .05 level.

  30. Income Spillovers Analysis: Log Wage Regression Results with Percentage with College or Higher Degrees by State, 18-64 year old males Dependent variable: log (weekly earnings). NOTE: All reported regressions also include the following independent variables: age and its square, three race/ethnic dummies, a marriage dummy, and two year dummies. Standard errors are in parentheses. Columns 4 and 6 include fifty state dummies. Columns 5 and 6 include 16 industry and 10 occupation dummies. * Statistically significant at the .10 level. ** Statistically significant at the .05 level.

  31. Income Spillovers Analysis: Log Wage Regression Results with Percentage with College or Higher Degrees by State, 18-64 year old females Dependent variable: log (weekly earnings) NOTE: All reported regressions also include the following independent variables: age and its square, three race/ethnic dummies, a marriage dummy, and two year dummies. Standard errors are in parentheses. Columns 4 and 6 include fifty state dummies. Columns 5 and 6 include 16 industry and 10 occupation dummies. * Statistically significant at the .10 level. ** Statistically significant at the .05 level.

More Related