200 likes | 302 Views
Social Networking Algorithms. related sections to read in Networked Life : 2.1,2.3 3.1 4.1 5.1 6.1-6.2 8.1 9.1. Google Search. PageRank algorithm crawling (follow hyperlinks embedded in HTML) >50 billion pages indexed (2012) (not counting intranets)
E N D
Social Networking Algorithms related sections to read in Networked Life: 2.1,2.3 3.1 4.1 5.1 6.1-6.2 8.1 9.1
Google Search • PageRank algorithm • crawling (follow hyperlinks embedded in HTML) >50 billion pages indexed (2012) (not counting intranets) source: http://www.statisticbrain.com/total-number-of-pages-indexed-by-google/ • indexing • assessing relevance: • number times keyword mentioned • proximity/order • title/heading, bold/fontsize • what makes a page “authoritative”? • users only look at top 3-10 hits, so what gets ranked at the top is crucial
Inverted Index • document retrieval • intersection of search terms • what about spelling errors, stemming, synonyms, semantic relationships? • more complex Boolean queries (or, not) • computation distributed over many computers using MapReduce • programming functions to distribute tasks and assemble results Document Collection (web pages): doc[0] = “all about the banana slug" doc[1] = “nutritional content of bananas" doc[2] = "bananas of the world“ doc[3] = “nutrition for athletes” query: “banana nutrition” {0,1,2}∩{1,3}={1}
the web-graph G=(V,E) • hyperlinks = directed edges • strongly connected components • adjacency matrix (sparse) • which pages are important? • number of connections (degree, centrality)? • number of in-edges (mentions/references)? Texas A&M Bowling League Members ... Joe ... www.tamu.edu Joe Student’s Home page. I am a student at Texas A&M I write code in Java Java java.sun.com
xi xj PageRank • need trust/reputation models? • “importance” of a node xi is based on: • importance neighbors who link to you (xJ) • weights 1/djdistribute a node’s importance over the nodes it links to • modify the equations to handle unlinked pages
system of coupled equations • iterative solutions • algorithms that start with random importances and adjust them until all the xi’s are mutually consistent (convergence) • in matrix form, this becomes an eigenvalue problem (hard to calculate) • x is a vector of importances • H is the weighted adjacency matrix x1=0.128 x2=0.159 x3=0.202 x4=0.150 x5=0.106 x6=0.044 x7=0.060 x8=0.145 x = Hx
The Network Effect • Metcalfe's law - the value of a telecommunications network is proportional to the square of the number of connected users of the system (n2) • going viral (videos and memes) • if you tell two friends, and they each tell 2 friends...it exponentially scales up to thousands of people in just a few steps • Small Worlds phenomenon • social networks not same as physical network • also scale-free topology (Power Law) • 6 degrees-of-separation (Milgram); community structure • crowd-sourcing – is there value in the aggregate opinion? • combines multiple experts (as well as boneheads and malefactors) • filters out bias of a few extreme opinions (since you don’t know who to trust)
Recommender Systems • Netflix, Pandora • how can we benefit from evaluations of others? • long-tail distribution for media • there are MANY movies, songs, etc. • most are rarely listened to • yet each individual has eclectic tastes • if a person likes X and Y, how to predict other Z? • similarity (collaborative filtering) • not just intersection of common features of X and Y • exploit what other people with similar tastes like • each user makes sparse recommendations • merge, and extract correlations; latent factors?
Machine Learning • other people who have watched movies with Ron Perlman tend to also like... • given a set of recommendations of users u for movies i: {(u,i)} or {rui}, build a predictive model • accuracy: • Netflix Prize • around 100 million anonymous ratings released as training set (1995-2001), 480k users, 17k movies • 2009: the grand prize of US$1,000,000 was given to the BellKor's Pragmatic Chaos team which bested Netflix's own algorithm for predicting ratings by 10.06%.
Aggregating Ratings • reviews on Amazon, TripAdvisor, Rotten Tomatoes (movies)... • trust, reputation, shills • weight each reviewer by consistency? • wisdom of the crowd • Galton’s experiment (1906), guessing the weight of an ox • subjectivity of hotel recommendations • can you trust the average weighting? • also depends on number of reviews, and dispersion (do # of 1’s matter?)
Auctions • examples: • Ebay • Google ad space (companies bid on search terms, position on page) • broadcasting spectrum (airwaves, FCC) • efficient, decentralized mechanism for resource allocation among many parties (exploit market forces) • goals: • maximize value for auctioneer • minimize cost for buyers; make bidding simple, not strategic • fairness, free of manipulation • utility functions (values to self-interested agents)
Auctions • types of auction mechanisms • public (open-outcry) vs. sealed-bid • ascending vs. descending • first-price vs. second-price • Vickrey (second-price, sealed-bid) auction • no incentive to under- or over-bid • no winner’s remorse • can show this is a Nash equilibrium strategy • current research: combinatorial auctions • bids for multiple items coupled together • algorithms for winner determination? (NP-hard)
Electronic Voting • Rank Aggregation • a social choice mechanism • unlike the US system, imagine you can vote for N candidates by ranking them in order of preference • other applications: vote for Olympics venues or baseball all-stars out a defined list of possibilities
Another example: Meta-search • merging search-engine results • Cynthia Dwork (WWW, 2001) • by merging top hits from google, bing, yahoo, altaVista, etc., could you get a better combined list? • search results are usually sparse – a given page might not be on every list of results • how should you rank page ranked 2nd, 3rd, and 101st? • what if one of the engines is paid to rank certain sites highly? (web-search “spam”)
among the many possible orderings (A<B<C, B<A<C...) is there a final ranking that is “most similar” to the most voters (representative)? • the Borda count • add up the voted ranks as weights • pros: sample, anonymous, neutral, consistent • cons: can be influenced by extreme votes that drag good candidates down
Condorcetalternative: the candidate that beats all others in pairwise comparisons • in this example, candidate Q wins based on Borda count, even though the majority of voters preferred P over Q
Condorcetalternative: the candidate that beats all others in pairwise comparisons • in this example, candidate Q wins based on Borda count, even though the majority of voters preferred P over Q P vs. Q: 2/3 prefer P P vs. R: 2/3 prefer P P vs. S: 2/3 prefer P Q vs. R: 3/3 prefer Q Q vs. S: 3/3 prefer P R vs. S: 3/3 prefer P P R Q S
Condorcetalternative: the candidate that beats all others in pairwise comparisons • in this example, candidate Q wins based on Borda count, even though the majority of voters preferred P over Q • generalization: Condorcet criterion • for each pair of candidates A and B, A must be ranked over B if the majority prefer A over B • Dwork showed there is a polynomial-time algorithm based on computing “locally Kemeney-optimal” rankings
ballot: a% new stadium b% new library c% fix roads d% hire new police 100%=1 vote Electronic Voting • complex (weighted) votes of preferences for multiple outcomes • example voting on funding of public projects to maximize public welfare • avoid the “free-rider” syndrome • “VCG” mechanism: penalize the winner by charging a tax based on how much he influenced result over alternative outcomes • encourages voters to vote their true beliefs
Summary • The value of networks grows more than linearly (quadratically?) with the number of people participating. • Algorithms like PageRank can identify “important” nodes in networks by analyzing connectivity (small-worlds topology). • There is “wisdom” in crowds. • Algorithms can aggregate preferences or rankings or ratings over multiple users to allow robust methods for determining combined/community opinion.