610 likes | 712 Views
Custom Fit or Off-the-Shelf Standards: Dilemma of Financial Reporting in Interactive World Economy. Shyam Sunder, Yale University III International Conference on Luca Pacioli in Accounting History III Balkans and Middle East Countries Conference on Accounting and Accounting History
E N D
Custom Fit or Off-the-Shelf Standards: Dilemma of Financial Reporting in Interactive World Economy Shyam Sunder, Yale University III International Conference on Luca Pacioli in Accounting History III Balkans and Middle East Countries Conference on Accounting and Accounting History Istanbul, Turkey,, June 19-22, 2013
An Overview • The world is more interactive today, compared to Pacioli’s world • Many economies of standardizing financial reporting across countries and industries; IASB and IFRS created to realize these economies • However, also significant diseconomies of standardization; dangers of granting monopoly powers to well-intentioned experts or politicians • The global financial crisis has already revealed some of the disadvantages; some even claim that this misguided standardization was a cause • Written enforced standards are not, and have never been, the only way to improve financial reporting; social norms is another approach • Doubtsvoiced in the U.S., China, Japan, India, and even Europe, about the wisdom of granting standards monopoly to a single body • Time for the emerging economies to rethink their own balance between for international and local standards; written rules and social norms • Influence others by persuasive force of ideas, not threat of punishment • If you don’t agree, consult Pacioli. Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Did Luca PacioliWrite Standards? • Summa elucidated accounting practice of its time • Its influence from its conformity to practice, acceptance by business, and usefulness • No powers of prescription or enforcement • More like Oxford English Dictionary than IFRS • Today, powerful, well-funded bureaucracies prescribe and enforce top down written rules; no prior experience in the field is needed Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Today’s World of Business and Standards • Great expansion of international investments and trade (beyond Pacioli’s Venetian merchants) • This international interactivity and expansion has been used as an argument for developing: • “… a single set of high quality, understandable, enforceable and globally accepted International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRSs) through its standard-setting body, the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB);” Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
IASB’s Argument for Its Monopoly • “My confidence that we are achieving this vision is bolstered by the strong case for global standards. In a world in which capital flows freely across borders, the same economic transaction should be accounted for in the same way, regardless of whether you are in Washington, Warsaw, Wellington or Winnipeg. Global standards make it easier for investors to make comparisons between companies operating in different jurisdictions. Multinational companies benefit from reduced compliance costs and reduced translation risks when consolidating multiple international subsidiaries into a single set of consolidated financial statements.” • Tweedie (2011) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
IASB’s Argument for Its Monopoly (continued) • “Global accounting standards will enhance the drive towards the free trade of capital internationally. By adopting a globally accepted set of standards, all companies—large and small—are able to attract capital from a larger pool of investors, driving down the cost of capital and facilitating cross-border mergers and acquisitions activity and strategic investments. Finally, a common set of standards eliminates opportunities for regulatory arbitrage and permits regulatory authorities to develop more consistent approaches to supervision across the world. In other words, financial reporting is a key element of post-crisis global regulation.” Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Even without IASB and IFRS • Most financial reporting jurisdictions allow a local monopoly in financial reporting standards for publicly-held corporations • In the United States, statutory authority of the Securities and Exchange Commission delegateedto the Financial Accounting Standards Board, retaining an oversight function • In some countries, standards specified through statutes in varying levels of detail. • A few countries—e.g., Switzerland and Canada—permit their corporations to choose among two or more sets of competing standards • But, monopoly is the reigning norm in most jurisdictions Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Let Us Rethink Standards • What are the functions of standards? • What improvements are achievable through standardization? • What are undesirable consequences of standardization? • After considering the arguments about its economies and diseconomies, what is a desirable scope of standardization? • How much should be written down, and how much should be left to social norms? • Should the written standards be domestic, regional or global? • Should they be specific to industries and size of firms? • Who should set the standards—government, private bodies or some combination of the two? • Is it better to grant standard-setting monopolies in specified jurisdictions (as granted to the FASB in the US and to the IASB in the European Union, and sought by the IASB across the world), or have multiple standard setters compete for clienteles who choose among alternative sets of standards? Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Functions of Standards • Two basic economic reasons (Jamal and Sunder 2007): • Quality through standards • Co-ordination standards Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Quality Standards • Food quality standards are a good example • Safety of food in restaurants by standards of quality and hygiene • Government standards are of often quality standards
Co-ordination through Standards(Often written in private sector)
Financial Reporting Standards • Roughly speaking • Disclosure standards are quality standards • Formatting standards are co-ordination standards • Measurement standards are mixed; they tend to serve some aspects of both quality as well coordination functions Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Advantages of Standards Well-Known • Learningand matching costs • Single aircraft airline • Standardized admissions tests • A standardized system of weights and measures • Giving preference, if not monopoly, to some systems and designs over others is the essential feature of all schemes of standardization (Sunder 1988 and 1997). Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Costs of Standards Less Obvious • Discourage innovation • No competitive motivation • Informational disadvantage of monopoly • QWERTY keyboard • Balancing costs and benefits of standards Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Scope of Standards • Domestic: traffic rules and signs for drivers • Regional: electrical adapters • Global: telecommunications • Industry-specific (real estate, films) and economy-wide standards • Size-specific and one standard for all sizes (IFRS for SMEs) • No comparability with a “single set” of standards Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
IASB’s Catch Phrases • “Single set”: Even individual countries have difficulty defending a single set of standards for all their companies in all industries; diversity of environment, legal, social and business institutions • “Comparability”: Does application of the same revenue recognition criterion in automobile and gold mining industries yield more comparable results? • “High quality standards”: What is quality? Pages? • “Lower cost of capital”: And lower rate of return? • “Promoting cross-border mergers”: Is that good or bad? For who? Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Why Written Standards? • It is fair and efficient to write down the regulatory standards for everyone to know and comply with (e.g., the Code of Hamurabi). • Written standards promote our sense of fair play in a democratic society to avoid arbitrariness and partiality • But all contingencies cannot be anticipated and written down. • Written standards constrain discretion in enforcement • They also serve as “road maps for evasion” and gaming to take advantage of the rules Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Why Clear Standards? • Clear standards make it easier to know what is permitted and what is not permitted. • No standard can be made “perfectly clear” • No matter how much detail we put in the rules, there will always be demand for further clarification and “guidance”; rule books grow • Do additional details in standards reduce or increase the loopholes? • 3 percent rule for Special Purpose Entities => Enron Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
A Static Ideal? • There exists an ideal set of written reporting and regulatory standards that, once discovered and implemented, will induce corporations and banks to function efficiently in conformity with the regulations • Dynamics of the game between managers and standard setters makes any such static ideal all but impossible • Regulatees see standards as constraints and modify their decisions to seek their own goals Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
People or Structure? • If we select knowledgeable, experienced, self-less, public-spirited, and wise individuals to constitute bodies that devise regulatory standards through deliberation and due process, we can improve the functioning of the economy. • Yes, but individuals stand where they sit. • We place much emphasis on the quality of individuals; • Insufficient attention given to the structure of game that regulators and regulatees play Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Crafting Standards through Deliberation • It is possible to construct or discover better written regulatory standards through deliberation in properly organized corporate entities (Basel Committee, Federal Reserve, IASB, etc.). • Assumes that such bodies can know the consequences of their actions (Cartesian perspective on the problem) • Little evidence in history to support this proposition • Written standards by authoritative bodies have repeatedly failed to yield their stated outcomes (e.g., global financial crisis) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Specialization in Setting Standards • Specialist standard setting bodies, standing ready to address new problems, inquiries and requests for clarifications help improve regulation • Their existence encourages a new “clarification” game targeted at them • They must keep a full agenda (performance) • Revenue and budget pressures • Over time, their written output must accumulate to a thick rule book (e.g., Basel I, II, III; IFRS) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Can They Distinguish Good from Bad Standards? • Standard setters can tell which written standards are better, and why; and what would happen if a rule were left unwritten • Little evidence that they know, or can know • For example, cost-of-capital is the result of complex interactions among many factors • These influences cannot be sorted out by ex ante analysis • Ex post analysis of data to assess the impact of regulatory standards is confounded with other factors which may have changed simultaneously (collinearity) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Regulatory Monopolies • Granting monopoly power in a given jurisdiction to standards written by a given body can help improve regulation; but • Informational disadvantage of a monopoly • No opportunity for experimentation • No opportunity to learn from the experience of alternatives; arrogance • No pressure to do better, or to correct errors • Pros and cons of regulatory competition Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Competition and Race to the Bottom • A regime that encourages reporting entities to choose among the standards written by competing organizations (and paying them a royalty for the privilege) induces a “race to the bottom” to devise less demanding standards • Many counter examples (Stock exchanges, bond rating services, appliance standards, college accreditation, bank regulation, corporate charters across 50 states in U.S., etc.) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Force and Effectiveness • Increase in the power of enforcement behind authoritative standards improves compliance and quality of regulation and reporting • Increased enforcement also increases resources devoted to evasion • Draconian punishments do not necessarily induce better behavior • Crime, alcohol and drug abuse (recent report on failure of the War on Drugs) • Cutting hands of thieves may not be an efficient way to reduce theft Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Statutory Approach Dominates Common Law • The quasi-statutory approach to setting regulatory standards (writing everything down) dominates a common law approach to financial reporting (leave significant parts unwritten, and subject to professional judgment) • Evidence? • Constitution (U.K., U.S., Singapore) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Are Written Standards Better than Social Norms? • Written standards backed by power of enforcement work better than unwritten social norms backed only by internal and external informal sanctions • Social norms govern great parts of our lives including many aspects of law • Insider trading example • Guilty beyond reasonable doubt • Private commercial codes (cotton, diamond trades in U.S.) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Are Financial Regulation and Reporting Improving? • 100 years of U.S. federal bank regulation and 80 years of federal regulation of securities and financial reporting has helped improve the quality of regulation. • Evidence? • Is a thicker rulebook indication of better regulation? • Perfect correlation between financial reports and stock returns? • How do we judge if regulations are getting better? Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Does Permitting Fewer Alternatives Yield Better Outcomes? • Fewer the alternatives permitted to the regulatees, the better the quality of regulation. • Fewer alternatives also tie the hands of the management of well-run companies who may wish to signal their confidence, competence and prospects by choosing reporting practices others find difficult to emulate. • Permitting fewer choices reduce information through signaling Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Monitor’s Bargaining Power • Well-specified standards enhance the bargaining power of the monitor/auditor vis-à-vis the regulated organization • Standards also encourage regulatee to demand: show me the rule • Reduced reliance on judgment • More detailed the standards, greater the part of monitor’s work that can be replaced by a computer, and lower the value of the service Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Individual responsibility • Written regulatory standards strengthen the individual responsibility of managers, regulators, auditors, and investment bankers for fair representation • On the contrary, they may undermine individual responsibility for fair representation and the big picture by shifting attention to meeting the letter, not spirit, of the specific provisions and their wording; check-box mentality Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
What about Education • Written standards help improve education and attract talent to the profession • Written standards degrade the class room from reasoning and intellectual debate to rote memorization • They make it less attractive to young talent Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Emphasis on Written Regulations • Reasonable arguments for written regulations • But also, reasonable limitations and criticisms of excessive dependence on written regulations • Examine some consequences of increasing dependence Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Basel II Bank Capital Regulation • 2007: Capital was 11 percent of risk-weighted assets for 10 largest US banks • But if you excluded goodwill, intangibles and deferred tax assets (which tend to become worthless under financial stress), their capital was only 2.8 percent Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
How Does Basel III Address this Problem? • More arcane and complex rules for calculating bank capital (opening more loopholes for financial engineering your way around the capital standards • Set the capital/asset requirement to 3 percent (about the same as the actual 2007 level) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Basel I, II, III, … and Counting • “Each new Basel (bank capital) standard attempts to correct the errors and unintended consequences of earlier versions. But instead of resulting in better outcomes, each do-over has been more complicated and less effective than the last. Most disturbingly, each fails to provide enough real capital to absorb unexpected shocks to the economy.” Thomas M. Hoenig (Vice-Chairman FDIC), “Get Basel III Right and Avoid Basel IV,” The Financial Times, December 12, 2012. Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Financial Engineering and Financial Regulation • These are just a few examples of the conflict between financial regulation and financial engineering. • How long can the regulatory walls hold? • Basel I proposed in 1988, and lasted for 16 years • Basel II proposed in 2004 and lasted less than half-a-dozen years (until the financial crisis 2007-10) • Basel III proposed in 2010, and has already been hollowed under industry pressure by the end of 2012, even before its implementation began Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Objectives in Financial Engineering • “The Financial Engineering Concentration encompasses the design, analysis, and construction of financial contracts to meet the needs of enterprises.” (Cornell’s ORIE M.S. concentration in financial engineering) • What are these needs? • In at least some cases, these needs consist of finding ways of • Reducing indebtedness on the balance sheet, or • Reducing expense on income statement, or • Increasing revenue on income statement, or • Increasing deductions on tax returns Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Securitization • A form of off-balance sheet financing which involves the pooling of financial assets • Risk transfer mechanism that allows loan originators to optimize balance sheet management • Allows highly rated securities to be created from less credit worthy assets • Can be in local or foreign currency, depending on client needs • A rapidly growing asset class with proven benefit for emerging market borrowers • For summaries of prior deals, please visit www.ifc.org/structured finance International Finance Corporation Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Off-Balance Sheet Financing • Borrow money in such a way so under the regulatory standards, it does not show up as a liability on the balance sheet. • That is, find a way around written standards so an obligation to pay does not show up as a liability in the financial reports. Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Does Financial Engineering Create Value • Allows highly rated securities to be created from less credit worthy assets •Payoffs of any asset can be partitioned into parts, some of which are more risky (and yield high return) and others are less risky and yield lower return • Can the sum of the values of these parts systematically exceed the value of the unpartitioned asset in absence of mis-information, mis-estimation, or extraneous cash consequences such as taxes? Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Financial & Regulatory Standards as Constraints on Financial Optimization • In such optimization, standards of financial regulation are treated as constraints • Most optimization problems have hard constraints—their violation brings well-specified penalties (dual prices) • With optimization confined by the production possibilities set and other such physical limitations, external constraints make a real difference to the final actions and outcomes • What kind of constraints do standards offer? • I am going to argue that these standards offer softer constraints because the forms of contracts, transactions, as well as organizational forms that businessmen can devise and use are beyond the scope of accounting standards Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Redesigning Contracts • A manufacturer needs to buy a machine for the factory • Borrowing is an option, but the manufacturer does not want more debt on its balance sheet • The leasing subsidiary of a bank buys the machine and gives it to the manufacturer on a long term lease—machine is in the factory but no debt on balance sheet! • FASB writes Standard 13: leases >90%V and >75%T must be treated as capital leases (debt is back on BS) • The bank revises the lease to levels below the thresholds specified in the standard (debt is off the BS) • FASB goes back to work, and so on … until the leases rulebook grows to over a 1,000 pages with no end to this growth in sight Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Redesigning Transactions • Depending on the current standards of financial reporting, transactions can be redesigned to achieve the desired consequences for revenues, expenses and taxes Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Redesigning the Organization • When design of contracts and transactions is not sufficient, organizations themselves can be redesigned, or new ones created in order to have the desired consequences for balance sheets, income statements and tax returns • Special purpose entities (SPEs and SPVs) are examples of organizations created for this purpose (see Klee and Butler 2002 and Gorton and Souleles 2005) • “Hundreds of respected U.S. companies are ferreting away trillions of dollars in debt in off-balance sheet subsidiaries, partnerships, and assorted obligations” (Henry et al. 2002) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
Asymmetric Game • Note that financial reporting standards neither have, nor can have, any say in any of these “business” decisions of the management • The role of the accountant and auditor is limited to preparing financial reports given all these decisions • While these decisions clearly consider what the accounting standards are, accountants have little freedom to take into account how and why these decisions were taken in the first place • There is great asymmetry between the freedom available to the business decision makers and constraints on the accountant who must abide by relatively rigid written standards in deciding how to report the performance and financial status of an organization Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards
The Net Effect • The decision to write an accounting standard is a matter of social policy that calls for a deliberative due process; it typically takes years to determine which rules might best serve investors and others. Inevitably, these standards are written on the assumption that the current forms of contracts, transactions, and organizations will continue to be used in the future when these standards are applied • The decision to change contracts, transactions and organization is an individual decision that may be taken within days if not hours. Further, the scope of these decisions is virtually unbounded (except by the imagination of the businessmen). Soon after the standards are issued, the environment to which they are applied changes relative to the what the standards were written for • The net effect: Financial reporting standards serve as relatively weak constraints (if at all) on what businesses can do and on what they report (relative to their underlying economics) Sunder: Financial Regulation Standards