1 / 58

Did fiscal stimulus end the recession?

Did fiscal stimulus end the recession? In the global recession of 2008 and 2009 most countries engaged in massive fiscal stimulus programs. Did these policies help to moderate the recession and speed the recovery?. 16. Fiscal Policy. CHAPTER CHECKLIST.

leewright
Download Presentation

Did fiscal stimulus end the recession?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Did fiscal stimulus end the recession? • In the global recession of 2008 and 2009 most countries engaged in massive fiscal stimulus programs. • Did these policies help to moderate the recession and speed the recovery?

  2. 16 Fiscal Policy CHAPTER CHECKLIST When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to • 1Describe the federal budget process and the recent history of revenues, outlays, deficits, and debts. • 2 Explain the supply-side effects of fiscal policy on employment and potential GDP. • 3 Explain the demand-side effects of fiscal policy on employment and real GDP.

  3. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • The federal budget is an annual statement of the revenues, outlays, and surplus or deficit of the government of the United States. • The federal budget has two purposes: • To finance the activities of the federal government • To achieve macroeconomic objectives • Fiscal policy is the use of the federal budget to achieve the macroeconomic objectives of high and sustained economic growth and full employment.

  4. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • The Institutions and Laws • The President and the Congress make the budget and develop fiscal policy on a fixed annual time line. • Fiscal year is a year that begins on October 1 and ends on September 30 of the next year.

  5. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • Budget Surplus, Deficit • Budget balance = Tax revenues – Outlays • The government has a balanced budget when tax revenues equal outlays (budget balance is zero). • The government has a budget surplus when tax revenues exceed outlays (budget balance is positive). • The government has a budget deficit when outlays exceed tax revenues budget balance is negative).

  6. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • Surplus, Deficit, and Debt • The government borrows to finance a budget deficit and repays its debt when it has a budget surplus. • The amount of debt outstanding that arises from past budget deficits is called national debt. • Debt at end of 2010 = Debt at end of 2009 + Budget deficit in 2010.

  7. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • The Federal Budget 2010

  8. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • On the tax revenues side of the budget: • The largest item is personal income taxes―taxes that people pay on wages and salaries and on interest. • The second largest item is Social Security taxes―taxes paid by workers and employers to fund Social Security benefits. • Corporate income taxes, which are the taxes paid by corporations on their profits, are much smaller. • Indirect taxes, the smallest revenue source, are sales taxes and customs and excise taxes.

  9. 16.1 THE FEDERAL BUDGET • On the outlays side of the budget: • The largest item is transfer payments. • Transfer payments are Social Security benefits, Medicare and Medicaid benefits, unemployment benefits, and other cash benefits paid to individuals and firms. • Expenditure on goods and services includes the government’s defense and homeland security budgets. • Debt interest is the interest on the national debt.

  10. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Schools of Thought and Cracks in Today’s Consensus • The three main schools of macroeconomic thought are classical, Keynesian, and monetarist macroeconomics. • Today’s consensus as one that takes insights from each of the schools. • While there is a consensus, the macroeconomic events of 2008 and 2009 have placed the consensus under some stress and cracks are emerging. • The main crack is between the views of Keynesian economists and others.

  11. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP The Keynesian View The Keynesian view is that fiscal stimulus—an increase in government outlays or a decrease in tax revenues—boosts real GDP and creates or saves jobs. Fiscal stimulus boosts real GDP and employment by increasing aggregate demand and the fiscal stimulus has a multiplier effect. Keynesians say that these positive effects of fiscal stimulus make it a vital and powerful tool in the fight against deep recession and depression.

  12. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • The Mainstream View • The mainstream view is that Keynesians overestimate the multiplier effects of fiscal stimulus and their effects are small, short-lived, and incapable of working fast enough to be useful. • Mainstream economists say that government stimulus “crowds out” investment. • The durable results of a fiscal stimulus are bigger government, lower potential GDP, a slower real GDP growth rate, and a greater burden of government debt on future generations.

  13. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Demand • Fiscal policy is a change in government outlays or in tax revenues. • Other things remaining the same, a change in any item in the government budget changes aggregate demand. • The change in aggregate demand has a multiplier effect— aggregate demand changes by a greater amount than the initial change in the item in the government budget.

  14. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP Government Expenditure Multiplier • The government expenditure multiplier is the effect of a change in government expenditure on goods and services on aggregate demand. • An increase in aggregate expenditure increases aggregate demand, which increases real GDP. • The increase in real GDP induces an increase in consumption expenditure, which further increases aggregate demand.

  15. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • The Tax Multiplier • The tax multiplier is the effect of a change in taxes on aggregate demand. • A decrease in taxes increases disposable income. • The increase in disposable income increases consumption expenditure and aggregate demand. • With increased aggregate demand, employment and real GDP increase and consumption expenditure increases yet further.

  16. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • So a decrease in taxes works like an increase in government expenditure. • Both actions increase aggregate demand and have a multiplier effect. • The magnitude of the tax multiplier is smaller than the government expenditure multiplier. • The reason: A $1 tax cut increases aggregate expenditure by less than $1 whereas a $1 increase in government expenditure increases aggregate expenditure by $1.

  17. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • The Transfer Payments Multiplier • The transfer payments multiplier is the effect of a change in transfer payments on aggregate demand. • This multiplier works like the tax multiplier but in the opposite direction. • An increase in transfer payments increases disposable income, which increases consumption expenditure. • With increased consumption expenditure, employment and real GDP increase and consumption expenditure increases yet further.

  18. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • The Balanced Budget Multiplier • The balanced budget multiplier is the effect on aggregate demand of a simultaneous change in government expenditure and taxes that leaves the budget balance unchanged. • The balanced budget multiplier is not zero—it is positive—because the government expenditure multiplier is larger than the tax multiplier.

  19. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • A Successful Fiscal Stimulus • If real GDP is below potential GDP, the government might pursue a fiscal stimulus by: • Increasing government expenditure on goods and services, • Increasing transfer payments, • Cutting taxes, or • A combination of all three. Cash for Clunkers was a fiscal stimulus.

  20. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP Figure 16.2 illustrates a fiscal stimulus. Potential GDP is $13 trillion, real GDP is $12 trillion, and 1.There is a $1 trillion recessionary gap. 2. An increase in government expenditure or a tax cut increases expenditure by ∆E.

  21. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP 3. The multiplier increases induced expenditure. The AD curve shifts rightward to AD1. The price level rises to 110, real GDP increases to $13 trillion, and the recessionary gap is eliminated.

  22. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • A Successful Contractionary Fiscal Policy • If real GDP is above potential GDP, the government might pursue a contractionary fiscal policy in an attempt to restore full employment. • Contractionary fiscal policy is a decrease in government expenditure on goods and services, a decrease in transfer payments, or an increase in taxes designed to decrease aggregate demand.

  23. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP Figure 16.3 illustrates contractionary fiscal policy. Potential GDP is $13 trillion, real GDP is $14 trillion, and 1.There is a $1 trillion inflationary gap. 2. A decrease in government expenditure or a tax rise decreases expenditure by ∆E.

  24. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP 3. The multiplier decreases induced expenditure. The AD curve shifts leftward to AD1. The price level falls to 110, real GDP decreases to$13 trillion, and the inflationary gap is eliminated.

  25. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Automatic and Discretionary Fiscal Stimulus • Fiscal policy action that are aimed at stimulating aggregate demand can be automatic or discretionary. • Automatic Fiscal Policy • Automatic fiscal policyis a fiscal policy action that is triggered by the state of the economy. • For example, an increase in unemployment induces an increase in payments to the unemployed or in a recession tax receipts decrease as incomes fall.

  26. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Discretionary Fiscal Policy • Discretionary fiscal policyis a fiscal policy action that is initiated by an act of Congress. • For example, an increase in defense spending or a cut in the income tax rate.

  27. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Automatic Fiscal Policy • A consequence of tax revenues and outlays that fluctuate with real GDP. • Automatic stabilizers are features of fiscal policy that stabilize real GDP without explicit action by the government. • Induced Taxes • Induced taxes are taxes that vary with real GDP.

  28. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Needs-Tested Spending • Needs-tested spending is spending on programs that entitle suitably qualified people and businesses to receive benefits— benefits that vary with need and with the state of the economy. • Induced taxes and needs-tested spending decrease the multiplier effects of change in autonomous expenditure and moderate both expansions and recessions and make real GDP more stable.

  29. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Discretionary Fiscal Policy • The use of discretionary fiscal policy is seriously hampered by four factors: • Law-making time lag • Shrinking area of law-maker discretion • Estimating potential GDP • Economic forecasting

  30. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Law-Making Time Lag • The amount of time it takes Congress to pass the laws needed to change taxes or spending. • This process takes time because each member of Congress has a different idea about what is the best tax or spending program to change, so long debates and committee meetings are needed to reconcile conflicting views.

  31. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Shrinking Area of Law-Maker Discretion • Expenditure on the military and on homeland security and very large expansion in expenditure on entitlement programs such as Medicare has increased. • The result is that around 80 percent of the federal budget is effectively off limits for discretionary fiscal policy action. • The 20 percent that is available for discretionary change include items such as education and the space program, which are hard to cut.

  32. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Estimating Potential GDP • It is not easy to tell whether real GDP is below, above, or at potential GDP. • So a discretionary fiscal action might move real GDP away from potential GDP instead of toward it. • This problem is a serious one because too much fiscal stimulation brings inflation and too little might bring recession.

  33. 16.2 THE DEMAND SIDE: STABILIZING REAL GDP • Economic Forecasting • Fiscal policy changes take a long time to enact in Congress and yet more time to become effective. • So fiscal policy must target forecasts of where the economy will be in the future. • Economic forecasting has improved enormously in recent years, but it remains inexact and subject to error. • So for a second reason, discretionary fiscal action might move real GDP away from potential GDP and create the very problems it seeks to correct.

  34. EYE on FISCAL STIMULUS Did Fiscal Stimulus End the Recession? In February 2009, in the depths of the 2008–2009 recession, Congress passed the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, a $787 billion fiscal stimulus package. This Act of Congress is an example of discretionary fiscal policy. Did this action by Congress contribute to ending the 2008–2009 recession and making the recession less severe than it might have been? The Obama Administration economists are confident that the stimulus package made a significant contribution to easing and ending the recession.

  35. EYE on FISCAL STIMULUS Did Fiscal Stimulus End the Recession? But many, and perhaps most, economists don’t agree. They think that the stimulus package played a small role and that the truly big story is not discretionary fiscal policy but the role played by automatic stabilizers. What were the fiscal policy actions and their likely effects? President Obama promised that fiscal stimulus would save or create 650,000 jobs by the end of the 2009 summer. In October 2009, the Administration economists declared that the fiscal stimulus had saved or created the promised 650,000 jobs.

  36. EYE on FISCAL STIMULUS Did Fiscal Stimulus End the Recession? This claim of success might be correct, but it isn’t startling and it isn’t a huge claim. Why? How much GDP would 650,000 people produce? In 2009, each employed person produced $100,000 of real GDP on average. So 650,000 people would produce $65 billion of GDP. But only 20 percent of the $787 billion stimulus package had been spent (or taken in tax breaks), so the stimulus was only about $160 billion. If government outlays of $160 billion created $65 billion of GDP, the multiplier was 0.4 (65/160 = 0.4).

  37. EYE on FISCAL STIMULUS Did Fiscal Stimulus End the Recession? This multiplier is much smaller than the 1.6 that the Obama economists say will eventually occur. They believe, like Keynes, that the multiplier starts out small and gets larger over time as spending plans respond to rising incomes. An initial increase in expenditure increases aggregate expenditure. But the increase in aggregate expenditure generates higher incomes, which in turn induces greater consumption expenditure.

  38. EYE on FISCAL STIMULUS Did Fiscal Stimulus End the Recession? Automatic Fiscal Policy Government revenue is sensitive to the state of the economy. When personal incomes and corporate profits fall, income tax revenues fall too. When unemployment increases, outlays on unemployment benefits and other social welfare benefits increase. These fiscal policy changes are automatic. They occur with speed and without help from Congress.

  39. EYE on FISCAL STIMULUS Did Fiscal Stimulus End the Recession? In 2009, real GDP fell to 6 percent below potential GDP—a recessionary gap of $800 billion. Tax revenues crashed and transfer payments skyrocketed. The figure shows that the automatic stabilizers were much larger than the discretionary actions. Automatic action played the major role in limiting job losses.

  40. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • Fiscal policy influences the output gap by changing aggregate demand and real GDP relative to potential GDP. • But fiscal policy also influences potential GDP and the growth rate of potential GDP. • These influences on potential GDP and economic growth arise because • The government provides public goods and services that increase productivity and • Taxes change the incentives the people face.

  41. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • Supply-side effects are the effects of fiscal policy on potential GDP. • Supply-side effects operate more slowly than the demand-side effects. • Supply-side effects are often ignored in times of recession when the focus is on fiscal stimulus and restoring full employment. • But in the long run, the supply-side effects of fiscal policy dominate and determine potential GDP.

  42. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • Full Employment and Potential GDP • The higher the real wage rate, other things remaining the same, the smaller is the quantity of labor demanded and the greater is the quantity of labor supplied. • When the real wage rate has adjusted to make the quantity of labor demanded equal to the quantity of labor supplied, there is full employment. • When the quantity of labor is the full-employment quantity, real GDP equals potential GDP.

  43. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • Fiscal Policy, Employment, and Potential GDP • Both sides of the government's budget influences potential GDP. • Public Goods and Productivity • The expenditure side provides public goods and services that enhance productivity. • The increase in productivity increases potential GDP.

  44. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • Taxes and Incentives • On the revenue side, taxes modify incentives and change the full-employment quantity of labor, as well as the amount of saving and investment. • An increase in taxes drives a wedge between the price paid by the buyer and the price received by a seller. • In the labor market, tax wedge is the gap between the before-tax wage rate and the after-tax wage rate. • The result is a decrease in the full-employment quantity of labor and a decrease in potential GDP.

  45. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • Full Employment with No Income Tax • The wage rate is $30 an hour and 250 billion hours of labor is employed.

  46. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH The economy is at full employment with 250 billion hours of labor employed. The production function shows that when 250 billion hours are employed, potential GDP is $14 trillion.

  47. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • The Effects of the Income Tax • The income tax • 1. Decreases the supply of labor. • 2. Creates a tax wedge between the wage rate that firms pay and workers receive.

  48. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH • 3. The before-tax wage rate rises to $35 an hour. • 4. The after-tax wage rate falls to $20 an hour. • 5. Full employment decreases to 200 billion hours.

  49. 16.3 THE SUPPLY SIDE: POTENTIAL GDP AND GROWTH 5. Full employment decreases to 200 billion hours. 6. Potential GDP decreases to $14 trillion.

More Related