1 / 20

INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE II: Federalism and Bicameralism

INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE II: Federalism and Bicameralism. Readings: Lijphart 185-215 and Russell. Guiding Questions . What is federalism? Confederation ? Unitary System? When do states adopt federal institutions? What is bicameralism? Do second chambers matter?. Dispersing Authority.

mab
Download Presentation

INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE II: Federalism and Bicameralism

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE II: Federalism and Bicameralism Readings: Lijphart 185-215 and Russell

  2. Guiding Questions • What is federalism? • Confederation? • Unitary System? • When do states adopt federal institutions? • What is bicameralism? • Do second chambers matter?

  3. Dispersing Authority • Democracies vary in the extent to which they centralize political authority. • Critical for understanding the political logic of a system • Tradeoffs between empowering the center vs. empowering the regions. • Critical: regional autonomy can be used as a basis for further autonomy or independence. • Examples: • 1) Spanish government and Catalan/Basque nationalists. • 2) British government and Scottish/Welsh nationalists • Three different ways to disperse authority.

  4. Federal, Confederal, and Unitary Systems • Unitary systems: • Political authority is vested within the central government. • Most European systems fall into this category • Confederation: • Political authority is vested within the subunits and central government is relatively weak. • Modern examples are rare • Switzerland sometimes referred to as a confederation • But this is debatable • Federalism: • Intermediate position between unitary systems and confederation. • Austria, Belgium, Germany, Switzerland, Bosnia and Herzegovina • European Union often seen as a “special case” of federalism

  5. Definition of Federalism • 1) State is divided between a central government and regional or sub national governments. • Typically, federalism is centered around a territorial component. • 2) Institutional powers are allocated between these levels of government. • Each unit is the “final arbiter” on certain issues. • 3) The levels possess at least some degree of autonomy from one another. • Neither level can unilaterally dissolve the other. • Example of a more consensual rather than a majoritarian political structure.

  6. Why Federalism? • Federalism typically attempts to reconcile social differences with a common national identity. • Often found in plural societies • Example: Belgium (linguistic communities), Switzerland (linguistic and religious divides). • Federalism often associated with large, diverse countries. • Examples: US (large vs. small state interests), Canada (Quebecois nationalism), etc. • Some exceptions • Germany • Neither large nor diverse • History of federalism is key • Modern German federalism aims to create uniform living standards across the Länder.

  7. Federalism and Bicameralism • Bicameralism: legislative systems with two chambers. • Dividing legislative authority across two chambers typically seen as consensual rather than a majoritarian trait. • Federal systems are typically bicameral. • First chamber (lower chamber) represents the national population. • Second chamber (upper chamber) represents the subunits. • In parliamentary systems, a confidence relationship exists between the government and the first chamber. • With few exceptions, this relationship does not extend to the second chamber. • Italy is an exception.

  8. Functions of the Second Chamber • Russell 2001 • 1) To represent an alternative set of interests than the first chamber. • Representation and redundancy aid policy refinement and protection of minority rights. • 2) To provide greater independence from political party influence in legislative scrutiny. • Congruence theoretically hinders legislative independence from central parties. • 3) Some act as a “veto player” within the parliamentary process. • Symmetry requires agreement by both chambers to pass legislation. • 4) Spread the legislative burden. • Limited agenda time makes an a second chamber a useful time saving device.

  9. Measuring Second Chamber Influence REPRESENTATION REDUNDANCY • Second chambers generally represent a different set of interests than the first chamber. • Originally a class based distinction. • Often seek to protect the rights of states or minority groups within the system. • Linguistic communities in Belgium • Länder in Germany • Different selection mechanisms offer alternative viewpoints and less partisan viewpoint. • Typically indirectly elected or appointed. • Smaller composition allows for greater interpersonal relationships between legislators. • Many second chambers intentionally endowed the with certain policy areas of expertise. • Law Lords/Bishops in the UK • Human rights in France

  10. Measuring Second Chamber Influence SYMMETRY CONGRUENCE • Ability to override the second chamber varies depending on the system. • Some chambers possess absolute veto authority. • This means that the agreement of the chamber is necessary for the passage of legislation. • Most second chambers possess suspensory veto authority • This means they can delay rather than defeat legislation. • The likelihood that the composition of the first and second chambers are similar. • In systems where the chambers are congruent, representation function may be compromised. • Similar chambers merely “duplicate” the work of the other. • Where chambers are incongruent, representation may be enhanced. • But, the second chamber may become a “second opposition.”

  11. Symmetric and Incongruent: German Bundesrat • STRONG BICAMERALISM • Symmetric and Incongruent • SYMMETRIC • Absolute/strong veto authority on all legislation touching on the prerogatives of the states. • Legislation passed by two-thirds in the Bundesrat can only be overridden by a two-thirds vote in the Bundestag. • There are 69 votes in the Bundesrat. • Majority is 35. • Votes must be cast en bloc in accordance with state government instructions. • Abstentions count as a no vote; land coalitions which cannot agree on a common position abstain.

  12. Symmetric and Incongruent: German Bundesrat • INCONGRUENT • Divided government occurs frequently • Seats are apportioned on the basis of population • Each Land receives between 3 and 6 votes. • Members are not directly elected • Appointed by Land governments • Land elections occur at four to five year intervals • Elections typically a referendum on current national government • Merkel government does not have a majority in the Bundesrat • Holds 25 votes and likely to lose more in upcoming elections.

  13. Asymmetric and Incongruent: UK House of Lords • MEDIUM BICAMERALISM • Asymmetric and Incongruent • Plays a major role in refining legislation. • Provides representation for the Church of England. • Included the highest appeals court until Supreme Court created in 2009. • Debates tend to be less politically charged than in the House of Commons. • All bills must be passed by both chambers of parliament unless the government invokes the Parliament Acts.

  14. Asymmetric and Incongruent: UK House of Lords • ASYMMETRIC: Veto authority removed by passage of the Parliament Acts • House of Lords maintained a strong/absolute veto over all legislation until 1911. • Absolute/strong vetoes: Defeat legislation outright. • Difficult to justify vetoing the legislation of an elected government. • Parliament Acts of 1911 • Gave the Lords a suspensory veto of two years • Suspensory veto: Delays but does not directly defeat legislation. • Parliament Acts of 1949 • Reduced this suspensory veto to one year. • Parliament Acts do not apply to bills that: • 1) Are initiated in the House of Lords • 2) Extend the life of the current Parliament • 3) Are considered “statutory instruments/delegated legislation” • Process takes a lot of time. • Only used four times since 1949

  15. Asymmetric and Incongruent: UK House of Lords • INCONGRUENT: No party has a majority in the House of Lords. • Many peers do not affiliate with any party. • 25 Bishops • Serve until 75. • 92 Hereditary peers • Holdovers from the House of Lords Act of 1999 which removed automatic right for hereditary peers to sit and vote in the Lords. • Elected by hereditary peers previously entitled to a seat under the old laws. • 23 Law Lords • Holdovers from previous system • New Law Lords sit the Supreme Court and will not take a peerage until they retire. • 686 Life peers • Appointed by PM or Commission. • Number is not fixed • Hereditary and life peers serve for life. • Cannot be removed save for bankruptcy.

  16. Asymmetric and Incongruent: UK House of Lords • Salisbury Doctrine historically shaped debate within the chamber. • Lords will typically not defeat legislation listed in a governing party’s manifesto. • Although this doctrine has weakened following the removal of hereditary peers. • Governments are defeated much more frequently in the Lords than in the Commons. • The confidence relationship does not extend into the Lords. • Defeat on a major piece of legislation does not imply a loss of confidence. • But it does mean that the government has to either: concede to the Lords, spend time overriding the Lords, or drop the bill. • Despite lack of strong/absolute veto authority the Lords still shapes outcomes • Expertise and suspensory veto authority give weight to the second chamber.

  17. Asymmetric and Congruent: Irish Seanad • WEAK BICAMERALISM • Asymmetric and Congruent • ASYMMETRIC • Seanad can delay legislation for six months. • Has only defeated the government a handful of times since its creation.

  18. Asymmetric and Congruent: Irish Seanad • CONGRUENT: Composition tends to mirror that of the Dáil. • Elections take place after elections for the Dáil. • Vocational boards: 43 • 5 boards consisting of TD’s, Senators and local councilors. • Nomination and election controlled by parties. • University seats: 6 • Directly elected by graduates of National University of Ireland and Trinity College Dublin • Typically independent • Taoiseach nominees: 11 • Typically members of his/her own party to ensure a government majority. • Most senators seek to return to the Dáil, thus central parties have a great deal of influence over their votes. • Senators wanting to be nominated to contest a Dáil do not want to anger their party,. • Independent senators have used their positions to advocate issues that major parties will not touch. • Example: Sen. Norris on civil unions.

  19. Conclusions: Second Chamber Reform • Several systems are debating second chamber reform. • Balancing legislative authority is a key factor in these debates. • Germany: rebalance the authority of the Bundestag with that of the Bundesrat • United Kingdom: hereditary peers removed but questions over how peers should be elected. • Ireland: questions over the relevance of the chamber have led to calls to boost its influence over European legislation or abolish the chamber altogether • Old issue of debate taking place in a different constitutional setting. • The idea of abolition is a non-starter in most systems • Referendum due in Ireland on this issue. • Sweden, Denmark, Norway, Iceland abolished their second chambers. • But these were special cases of bicameralism • Increasing veto authority is not an option. • Governments do not want to risk more defeats. • Greater reliance on second chambers increases their bargaining authority regardless of veto strength. • Expertise in the second chamber also a valuable commodity for governments. • But whether or not this would be protected if chambers were directly elected is debatable.

  20. Next Unit • Institutional Structure: Majoritarian vs. Consensus Politics • Reading: Lijphart 9-21, 31-47, 243-309 • PAY PARTICULAR ATTENTION TO: • 1) Effects on economic policy. • 2) Effects on social policy. • 3) Patterns of change within systems.

More Related