240 likes | 386 Views
A LOOK BACK: CALIFORNIA STATE ROUTE 91 . Edward C. Sullivan, California Polytechnic State University, San Luis Obispo. Facility Features. 4 lane toll road in median of 8 lane freeway 16 km. in length Express travel (no intermediate access) Heavy vehicles not permitted
E N D
A LOOK BACK: CALIFORNIA STATE ROUTE 91 Edward C. Sullivan, California Polytechnic State University, San Luis Obispo
Facility Features • 4 lane toll road in median of 8 lane freeway • 16 km. in length • Express travel (no intermediate access) • Heavy vehicles not permitted • Electronic toll collection only (no cash) • Time-dependent tolls, reflecting demand • Originally constructed and operated by private company under franchise agreement with the State
Genesis – Calif. AB 680 (1989) • Goals of the legislation: • Attract “alternate funding sources” to meet state transportation needs • Gain private sector efficiencies in developing projects • Reduce congestion in crowded corridors • Provide alternate route selections • Provide private partners a “reasonable” profit
Provisions of AB 680 • 4 demo projects w/ geographic distribution • Provides up to 35 year lease of right-of-way and airspace, which then reverts to the State (but may remain a toll road) • Projects become part of the state highway system • Must meet all applicable laws, environmental requirements, and be built to State standards • Any State services fully compensated; state powers (e.g. condemnation) made available • “Excess” tolls either go to the State or used to reduce project debt
The State Route 91 Impact Assessment Study • Objective: measure reactions to variable toll pricing and the other innovative features of the toll facility • Impacts tracked from mid-1994 through 1999 (one year after opening day)
The State Route 91 Impact Study – Focus Areas • Traffic counts, occupancy counts and speeds • Effects on corridor bus, rail and park & ride • Effects on accidents and significant incidents • Traffic operations at entrances/exits • Origin-destination (revealed preference) surveys • Public opinion surveys • Emissions modeling • Calibration of choice models
Findings – Tolls & Time Savings • Express lane use strongly reflects hourly travel time savings • Flattening of traffic peaks is weakly responsive to tolls – more responsive in the AM period • Commuters typically overestimate time saved by 5-30 minutes • Some users cite driving comfort & safety to justify paying tolls if time saving is minimal • About 18% do not pay their own tolls
Findings – User Demographics • Income correlates positively with use frequency for all groups • Middle-income groups seem relatively most affected by toll increases • Being female strongly correlates with using the toll lanes • Middle age groups use toll lanes more than the youngest and oldest age categories • More education also correlates with toll lane use
Lessons Learned About User Demographics • Results from CA Route 91 show a moderate income effect in travelers’ use of the toll lanes • Nevertheless many frequent users are low income, and many high income commuters are infrequent or non-users • Having said all this, the choice to use the optional toll lanes seems more related to current travel conditions and needs than to user demographics
Findings – Ridesharing & Transit • Toll incentives were accompanied by long-term increase in 3+ ridesharing • HOV users have been more likely to use X-lanes • Flexible work schedules seem unrelated to X-lane use • No significant impacts on corridor transit use (public transit is about 1% of total corridor travel)
Findings – Collision Experience • Accident rates in the corridor have generally varied with congestion – there appear to be no particular effects related to the special operating characteristics of the toll lanes
Findings – Public Opinion • 91X lanes’ image suffered in 98-99 from disputes about ownership & congestion • Approval of variable tolls fell but overall approval of toll financing remains high • Toll payers express higher approval of variable tolls than non-payers • Approval declined for private operation • Approval of HOT lane concept is high
Seeds of De-Privatization • Traffic growth led to substantial renewed congestion • Some partners changed business strategy and wanted out • A 1999 buy-out offer from start-up non-profit (New-Trac) for $260 million was widely perceived as sweetheart deal contrary to public interest, with a major political outcry • A 1999 CPTC lawsuit against Caltrans stopped planned capacity improvements (Caltrans settled) • A 2000 Riverside County lawsuit against CPTC and Caltrans tried to void the franchise agreement • At least two unsuccessful legislative bills (AB 1091, AB 1346) sought to void the non-compete clause and have the public acquire the toll lanes by condemnation • In 2001, CPTC successfully refinanced $135 million in debt to pay loans from partners and cover remaining construction debt at 7.63% rather than 9%
De-Privatization Arrives • In spring 2002, the CPTC and the Orange County Transportation Authority (OCTA) agreed to a sale of the 91 franchise for $207.5 million • In fall 2002, the governor signed AB 1010 which, among other things, authorizes the transfer • The sale became final in January, 2003 • CPTC metamorphosed into Cofiroute Global Mobility, which now operates SR 91 for OCTA
Provisions of AB 1010 (2002) • Authorizes OCTA to buy the CPTC franchise • Calls for improving congestion by eliminating the non-compete clause • Calls for reduced SR 91 tolls and a minimum toll period • All projects become non-toll when franchises expire • No more new franchises after January 1, 2003 • OCTA prohibited from transferring its franchise without State approval • Creates an SR 91 advisory committee with strong local political control
A Good Deal for All • CPTC receives $135 million to cover its (newly refinanced) debt plus $72 million for the original partners • OCTA can use a 30 year payback schedule of $13 million per year • An Ernst & Young study for OCTA predicts $40.5 revenue by 2010 with daily traffic to grow from 25,500 in 2001 to nearly 64,000 in 2030 • HOV-3+ again travel free (except during the worst of the afternoon peak, where the 50% toll is maintained) • In Nov., 2002, voters approved Measure A to provide nearly $1/2 billion in road improvements elsewhere in the 91 corridor, which would have been blocked by the non-compete clause
In Retrospect • Despite de-privatization, the SR 91 project was a very successful project on many dimensions • It was an innovative model that helped establish in the U.S. an open mind toward market-based road pricing • It proved that public-private highway partnerships can be financially successful • The Achylles heal of this privatization project turned out to be the non-compete clause in the franchise agreement
More Final Observations • Public-private infrastructure projects should be eligible for tax-exempt bonds, even with a for-profit private partner (OCTA debt will be about 5.5%, compared to CPTC’s 7.6%) • SR 91 showed the value in having the public partner obtain prior environmental clearance, on a reimbursement basis • Given the resource limitations of most public transportation authorities, the SR 91 non-compete clause was probably neither needed nor desirable
The “Bottom Line” • CA Route 91 has demonstrated that innovative road pricing (premium service for a premium price) can be economically attractive, win public approval, and significantly influence travel behavior. • Increasing traveler options is a subtle yet powerful outcome from such value pricing projects. • “One size fits all” in road pricing has clearly failed. Increasing transportation choices through pricing has succeeded in CA and deserves careful consideration elsewhere.