90 likes | 298 Views
Making sense of Article 101 TFEU Economic insights. Pablo Ibanez Colomo London School of Economics. What we know and what we do not know about Article 101(1) TFEU. A restriction by object is established in light of the nature and the context of the agreement
E N D
Making sense of Article 101 TFEUEconomic insights Pablo Ibanez ColomoLondon School of Economics
What we know and what we do not know about Article 101(1) TFEU • A restriction by object is established in light of the nature and the context of the agreement • The subjective intent of the parties is not a decisive factor... • ...nor is the formal dimension of the restraints (price-fixing, market sharing) • How is that different from the assessment of restrictive effects under Article 101(1) TFEU? • And from the question of whether the agreement satisfies the conditions of Article 101(3) TFEU?
What we know and what we do not know about Article 101(1) TFEU • The category of object restrictions encapsulates a presumption of some sort • ...but an agreement may restrict competition by object irrespective of its effects • In fact, EU courts examine the restrictive nature of the agreement (‘by its very nature’)
What we know and what we do not know about Article 101(1) TFEU • The pro-competitive aspects of the agreement are not irrelevant under Article 101(1) TFEU • This means that some form of balancing must take place under the paragraph (Metro II)... • ... but the analysis of these considerations remains relatively ‘abstract’ (Mastercard)... • ...and has to be different from the assessment of agreements under Article 101(3) TFEU
What is a restriction by object? • Is not it all about the plausibility of an efficiency explanation for a restraint? • Analysis of the nature and context of the agreement = plausibility of the explanation • The form of the restraint (price-fixing, market sharing) is as such irrelevant • Absent a plausible efficiency explanation, anticompetitive intent can safely be presumed • Likewise, it is presumed that the agreement does not have pro-competitive effects, not the opposite
What is a restriction by object? • The case law can be systematised in light of this interpretation • Systematic assessment of the rationale behind the agreement (Nungesser, Pronuptia, Delimitis...) • Influence of the context on the conclusions (John Deere vs. Asnef-Equifax vs. T-Mobile) • Recent prominence of the rhetoric of ‘objective justification’ (Pierre Fabre)
What is a restriction by object? • This interpretation needs to be qualified in some cases • Market integration: the test seems to become one of necessity (vs. plausibility): Coditel II, Erauw • Vertical price-fixing seems to be examined in a different light (Binon, Pronuptia)
Assessing restrictions by effect • The pro-competitive dimension of the agreement is relevant to establish its nature • Efficiency gains are not quantified nor balanced against negative effects under Article 101(1) TFEU • Any balancing under Article 101(1) TFEU is thus based on presumptions (Mastercard) • Again, some support in the case law: • Metro I, Metro II and selective distribution • Gottrup-KlimandWouters
What role for Article 101(3) TFEU? • The explicit quantification of efficiency gains would be relevant where: • Restraints that cannot be plausibly explained on efficiency grounds (BIDS) • Agreements with the potential to have serious anticompetitive effects (Interbrew) • Agreements restricting parallel trade (GlaxoSpain) or providing for RPM (Guidelines) • Compare: efficiencies in merger control and objective justification under Article 102 TFEU