200 likes | 429 Views
Computing Best-Response Strategies in Infinite Games of Incomplete Information. Daniel Reeves and Michael Wellman University of Michigan. Definitions. Infinite Game = infinite action spaces Incomplete Information = payoffs depend on information that is private to the players
E N D
Computing Best-Response Strategies in Infinite Games of Incomplete Information Daniel Reeves and Michael Wellman University of Michigan
Definitions • Infinite Game = infinite action spaces • Incomplete Information = payoffs depend on information that is private to the players • Type = a player’s private information • One-shot Game = players each choose a single action simultaneously and then immediately receive a payoff • Strategy = a mapping from type to action • Best-Response Strategy = optimal strategy given known strategies of the other players • Nash Equilibrium = profile of strategies such that each strategy is a best response to the others • Bayes-Nash Equilibrium = generalization of NE to the case of incomplete information, for expected-utility maximizing players
Finite Game Approximations • Finite game solvers: • Gambit • Gala • Gametracer • Why not discretize? • Introduces qualitative differences • Computationally intractable
Our Class of Games • 2-player, one-shot, infinite games of incomplete information • Piecewise uniform type distributions • Payoff functions of the form:
Games in our Class Other games: War of Attrition, Incomplete info versions of Cournot and Bertrand games
Piecewise Linear Strategies • Specified by the vectors c, m, b
Existence and Computation of Piecewise Linear Best Responses • Theorem 1: Given a payoff function with I regions as above, an opponent type distribution with cdf F that is piecewise uniform with J pieces, and a piecewise linear strategy function with K pieces, the best response is itself a piecewise linear function with no more than 2(I-1)(J+K-2) piece boundaries.
The Proof • For arbitrary own type t, and opponent type a random variable T, find own action a maximizing ET[u(t,a,T,s(T))] • (Numerical maximization not applicable due to parameter t) • Above works out to be a piecewise polynomial in a (parameterized by t) • For given t, finding optimal a is straightforward • Remains to find partitioning of type space such that within each type range, optimal action is a linear function of t • This can be done in polynomial time
Example: First-Price Sealed Bid Auction (FPSB) • Types (valuations) drawn from U[0,1] • Payoff function: • Known Bayes-Nash equilibrium (McAfee & McMillan, 1987): a(t)=t/2 • Found in as few as one iteration from a variety of seed strategies
Example: Supply-chain Game • Producers’ Costs U[0,1] • Consumer’s Valuation v in [1.5,3] (known) • Payoff function: bid-cost if bid+bid2 <= v 0 otherwise Consumer Producer 1 Producer 2
Proving a Bayes-Nash Equilibrium • Candidate Strategy: • Compute best response… 2/3 v – 1/2 if cost < 2/3 v – 1 cost/2 + v/3 otherwise
Computing Best Response Expected payoff , EP(b) =(b-c)*p(b+b2<=v) =(b-c)*[p(c2<=2/3v-1)*p(b+2/3v-1/2<=v | c2<=2/3v-1) +p(c2>2/3v-1) * p(b+c2/2+v/3<=v | c2 > 2/3v-1)] =(b-c)*[(2/3v-1)*p(b<=v/3+1/2) +p(2/3v-1 < c2 < 4/3v-2b)] Case 1: b<=2/3v-1/2 EP(b) = (b-c)*[(2/3v-1)*1 + (2-2/3v)] = (b-c) ==> b* = 2/3v-1/2 ==> EP1(b*) = 2/3v-1/2-c Case 2: 2/3v-1/2 < b < v/3+1/2 EP(b) = (b-c)*[(2/3v-1)+(2/3v-2b+1)] = (b-c)*(4/3v-2b) ==> b* = c/2+v/3 ==> EP2(b*) = (3c-2v)^2/18 Case 3: b > v/3+1/2 ==> EP3(b) = 0
Computing Best Response (2) EP1(b*) > EP2(b*) iff c < 2/3 v – 1 Therefore, best-response is… 2/3 v – 1/2 if c < 2/3 v – 1 c/2 + v/3 otherwise
Example: Bargaining Game • (aka, sealed-bid k-double auction) • Buyer and seller place bids, transaction happens iff they overlap • Transaction price is some linear combination of the bids • Known equilibrium (Chatterjee & Samuelson, 1983) for seller (1) and buyer (2): • Found in several iterations from truthful bidding
Provision Point Mechanism • (aka, Public Good or Voluntary Participation game) • 2 agents want to jointly acquire a good costing C • Mechanism: simultaneously offer contributions; buy iff sum > C and split the excess (C – sum) evenly • Nash: 2/3 t + C/4 – 1/6
Shared-Good Auction • New mechanism, similar to the divorce-settlement game; undoes provision-point • Agents place bids for a good they currently share, valuations ~U[A,B] • High bidder gets the good and pays half its bid to the low bidder in compensation
Equilibrium in Shared-Good Auction • Found in one iteration from truthful bidding (for any specific [A,B])
Vicious Vickrey Auction • Generalization of a Vickrey Auction (Brandt & Weiss, 2001) to allow for disutility from opponent’s utility (eg, business competitors) • Brandt & Weiss consider only the complete information version
Equilibrium in Vicious Vickrey • a(t) = (k+t)/(k+1) • Reduces to truthful bidding for the standard Vickrey Auction (k=0) • Iterated best-response solver finds this equilibrium (for specific values of k) within several iterations from a variety of seed strategies
Conclusions • First algorithm for finding best-response strategies in a broad class of infinite games of incomplete information • Confirms known equilibria (eg, FPSB), confirms equilibria we derive here (Supply-Chain game), discovers new equilibria (Shared-good auction, Vicious Vickrey) • Goal: characterize the class of games for which iterated best-response converges