1 / 29

Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas are not Arbitrage-Free

Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas are not Arbitrage-Free. The Risk Discount Function The Casualty Actuarial Society Spring 2003 Meeting Marco Island, Florida. Summary of Main Points. Roulette-like binary derivatives Arbitrage-free pricing Same probabilities  different payoffs

nam
Download Presentation

Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas are not Arbitrage-Free

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Distribution-Based Pricing Formulas are not Arbitrage-Free The Risk Discount Function The Casualty Actuarial Society Spring 2003 Meeting Marco Island, Florida

  2. Summary of Main Points • Roulette-like binary derivatives • Arbitrage-free pricing Same probabilities  different payoffs • Distribution-based formulas cannot model this • Risk Discount Function characterizes risk measurement

  3. Overview of Main Points • Derivatives can be created from call options that are equivalent to roulette-like bets on the stock price. • Probabilities and payoffs are calculated with the Black-Scholes pricing model, which is arbitrage-free. • Unlike actual roulette, two bets with identical probabilities will generally have different payoff ratios. • A distribution-based risk load formula would assign the same risk load to bets having identical probabilities, so it cannot reproduce Black-Scholes prices. • The result holds in general: Risk load formulas that use only the outcome distribution do not produce arbitrage-free prices. • The “Risk Discount Function” characterizes risk measurement, and distinguishes between investment and hedging derivative types.

  4. Derivative-as-Wager Concept • The ray derivative is binary. • Binary derivatives are like bets. • The bet is on whether the stock price will be above 120 at expiration, or not. • Similar to a roulette bet, with different odds and payoff.

  5. Since it’s a bet… What are the odds, and what’s the payoff? • Black-Scholes implies lognormal prices, so can use a normal table to get odds. • Probability of winning = 33% • Black-Scholes price = 0.2551 • You bet $25.51, you have a 33% chance of winning, you get $100 in a year if you win.

  6. Is this a good bet? • NPV Expected Gain Analysis: • PV($100) at 4% = $96.15 • Expected = 33% ($96.15) = $31.73 • Expected Net @ PV = $31.73 - $25.51 = $6.22 • Return Analysis • Exp’d Return = $33.00 / $25.51 – 1 = 29% • Choice: 4% risk-free or 29% exp’d + risk

  7. Risk Discount Concept • Bond prices are discounted based on risk. • More risk  higher yield  more discount relative to the price of a risk-free bond. • Example: 5% 1-year, when risk-free = 4%: • Price = $1,000 / 1.05 = $952.38 • Risk-free price = $1,000 / 1.04 = $961.54 • Discount Factor = $952.38 / $961.54 = 99.05% • Discount Factor = Price / Discounted Face Value

  8. Risk Discount Concept • Same reasoning applies to any instrument: • Expected yield > risk-free  discount in price • Risk Discount Factor = Price / PV[Expd Value] • Risk Discount Factor = $25.51 / $31.73 = 80% • Can also ratio risk-free / expected yield: • Risk Discount Factor = 1.04 / 1.29 = 80%

  9. Risk Discount Factor for Binary • Rays are binary derivatives • Payoff = $1 if win, $0 if loss • Expected Value = Probability of win • Risk Discount = Price / PV[Probability] • Risk Discount = 0.2551 / (.33/1.04) = 80%

  10. Segment Derivative • Bet on: Expiration price between 120 and 150 • Probability = 33.00% - 11.82% = 21.17% • Price = 0.2551 – 0.0819 = 0.1732 • Lower price, lower odds than the ray • Is this a better or worse bet than the ray?

  11. Segment Derivative • Analysis: Better or worse than ray? • Exp’d Return = 0.2117 / 0.1732 – 1 = 22% • Win probability lower than ray  more risk • Less expected return than the A*(120) ray • The ray would be a better bet • Risk Discount = 0.1732 / (0.2117 / 1.04) = 85% • Not as much discount in price as ray has

  12. Roulette • Wheel with 38 equally-likely spaces, numbered “00” and “0” through “36” • Probability of win = 1/38 • $1 bet pays $36 (including return of $1 bet) • Same as binary derivative • Negative expected return: • Expected return = (1/38)($36) – 1 = -5% • Risk Surcharge Factor = $1 / ($36/38) = 106%

  13. Map derivatives to roulette wheel • You can choose boundary prices for segments and rays for any win probability. • Split up the entire price range into 38 segments and one ray, so that each of them has the same 1/38 probability.

  14. Map derivatives to roulette wheel • Each segment / ray has the same odds as a roulette wheel space: p(win) = 1/38. • All have the same outcome distribution: • P(value = $1) = 1/38 • P(value = $0) = 37/38

  15. If the odds are just like roulette, how are the payoffs? • Surprising fact: The spaces on this wheel all have different payoffs. • Space “00” pays $25 (worst space) • Space “12” pays $36 (like a normal wheel) • Space “16” pays $38 (breakeven bet) • Space “36” pays $60 (best space)

  16. Key points from example • All spaces have the same probability distribution. • All outcomes are determined by the same event, the stock price at expiration (like the wheel’s spin). • All have different arbitrage-free prices.

  17. Why doesn’t everyone bet on space 36? • One reason: People need hedges against economic risks that naturally arise in the course of business and living. • Risk of loss of equity in a business. • Risk of loss of house in a hurricane. • Same reason a business founder sells stock in an IPO for cash: less expected return, but hedge against potential loss • Lower-numbered spaces are hedges, like put options. • Higher-numbered spaces are speculative investments.

  18. Arbitrage • Roulette: Only one side available • Players, not casino, set the bets • If you could bet from the casino’s side, you’d bet on every number  certain win • This is arbitrage • Securities markets: Either side available (short or long), and player sets the bets

  19. Arbitrage • If all spaces have same payoff, it has to be $38, or else arbitrage is possible • $38 payoff  zero risk load • Only two possibilities: • All spaces pay $38 for $1 bet • Spaces have varying payoffs

  20. Distribution-based risk load formulas are not arbitrage-free • A distribution-based risk load formula gives the same risk load to risks that have the same distribution. • Unless the risk load = 0, this will not produce arbitrage-free prices.

  21. The Risk Discount Function • The central function that describes: • when risk is compensated by return, and how much (investment or speculation) • when risk assumption is surcharged (hedging or insurance)

  22. Further Reading: Ruhm-Mango • Paper presented at Bowles Symposium, April 2003 by David Ruhm and Donald Mango • Ruhm-Mango theorem: Any formula that produces additive prices has a risk discount function at its core, which completely describes it (up to a scale factor). • The underlying risk discount function is like a pricing method’s DNA. It contains all of the method’s risk-pricing information. • All additive pricing formulas can be condensed to one: Price = W (E[R] + Cov[Z,R]) with Z = underlying risk discount function. • This formula produces Black-Scholes, CAPM, etc. prices.

More Related