200 likes | 328 Views
Selecting Growth Measures for School and Teacher Evaluations: Should Proportionality Matter?. Mark Ehlert Cory Koedel Eric Parsons Michael Podgursky Department of Economics, University of Missouri -Columbia. Motivation.
E N D
Selecting Growth Measures for School and Teacher Evaluations: Should Proportionality Matter? Mark Ehlert Cory Koedel Eric Parsons Michael Podgursky Department of Economics, University of Missouri -Columbia
Motivation • Growth models are increasingly being incorporated into district, school and teacher evaluations across the United States. • The question of how to model student test-score growth has resulted in lively policy debates • What are objectives of the evaluation system?
Summary of Findings • We argue that the three key objectives of an evaluation system in education are: • Elicit optimal effort from agents • Provide useful performance signals to educational actors • Avoid exacerbating pre-existing inequities in the labor markets faced by advantaged and disadvantaged schools • Given these objectives, the proper growth model for use in evaluation systems is neither the sparse model or a traditional VAM model. Instead, it is what we call the “proportional” VAM model.
A Model Menu • The growth-model choice set essentially comes down to these three choices: • The sparse model (e.g., SGPs) • A single-equation VAM model (e.g., a standard value-added model from the research literature). • The proportional model (e.g., a two-step fixed effects model or random-effects model, less common in research)
http://www.leg.state.nv.us/session/76th2011/exhibits/assembly/ed/aed1013c.pdfhttp://www.leg.state.nv.us/session/76th2011/exhibits/assembly/ed/aed1013c.pdf
Comparing the One-Step and Two-Step VAMs • The key difference is that the two-step VAM partials out variation in test scores attributable to student and school characteristics before estimating the school effects. • Specific example: Suppose that high-poverty schools really are of lower quality (causally). • In the one-step VAM, the model identifies poverty effects (F/R lunch) using within-school variation in student poverty status so it can separately identify differences in school quality between high- and low-poverty students • In the two-step VAM, the first step attributes any and all systematic performance differences between high- and low-poverty students to the first-step variables (e.g., it purges them from the residuals), including systematic differences in school quality. • The implication is that high- and low-poverty schools are only compared to each other in the model output – not to dissimilar schools.
Missouri Schools, Median SGPs r = -.37
Objective #1: Elicit optimal educator effort • Barlevy and Neal (2012) cover this issue extensively. • There is also a large literature in economics, outside of the education-evaluation context, that is very clear on how to design evaluation systems when some competitors are at an inherent disadvantage (e.g., see Schotter and Weigelt (1992), who study this issue in the context of affirmative action policy) . • A central lesson from these studies is that the right signal must be sent to agents in different circumstances to elicit optimal effort. This signal need not be a direct measure of absolute productivity; instead, it should be an indicator of performance relative to equally-circumstancedpeers. • This is precisely what the proportional model does (based on observable circumstances).
Objective #1: Elicit optimal educator effort • Limitation: There is some evidence that the effort response margin in education in the United States is weak (Springer et al., 2010; on other hand … Fryer, et. al., 2012).
Objective #2: Provide useful performance signals • It is a common conventional wisdom that growth-model output doesn’t help educational actors improve. Is this really true? • Growth model output can: • Encourage effective schools (districts/teachers) to continue to refine and augment existing instructional strategies • Serve as a point of departure for interventions/overhauls in ineffective schools (districts/teachers) • Facilitate productive educator-to-educator learning by pairing low- and high-performing schools (districts/teachers). • The signaling value of an evaluation system is particularly important when it is difficult for individual schools (districts/teachers) to assess their performance, and the performance of others, accurately.
Objective #2: Provide useful performance signals • We argue that the most useful performance signals come from the two-step “proportional” model. • This is true even under the maintained assumption that the one-step VAM produces causal estimates. • A key reason is that the causal estimates from the one-step VAM do not account for the counterfactual. • Example: Disadvantaged schools face weaker educator labor markets (Boyd et al., 2005; Jacob, 2007; Koedel et al., 2011; Reininger, 2012) • Sparse models provide the least-useful performance signals (not controversial: acknowledged in SGP literature)
Example What do we tell Rough Diamond and Gold Leaf? What do we tell other schools about Rough Diamond and Gold Leaf?
Objective #3: Labor-market inequities • The labor-market difficulties faced by disadvantaged schools have been well-documented (Boyd et al., 2005; Jacob, 2007; Koedel et al., 2011; Reininger, 2012). • As stakes become attached to school rankings based on growth models, systems that disproportionately identify poor schools as “losers” will make positions at these schools even less desirable to prospective educators.
Summary thus far… • We identify three key objectives of an evaluation system in education: • Elicit optimal effort from agents • Provide useful performance signals to educational actors • Avoid exacerbating pre-existing inequities in the labor markets faced by advantaged and disadvantaged schools • When one considers these key objectives, the “proportionality” feature of the two-step model is preferred on all three.
But what about… • The fact remains that schools serving disadvantaged students really do have lower test scores, and lower unconditional growth, than schools serving advantaged students. • There seems to be general concern that this information will be hidden if we construct proportional growth models. • Our view is that this concern is largely misguided.
Concluding Remarks • Growth models are quickly (very quickly) moving from the research space to the policy space. • The policy uses for growth models are not the same as the research uses for growth models. • Starting with the right question is important: “What are the objectives of the evaluation system?” • Beginning with this question, in our view, leads us to conclude that a “proportional” growth model is best-suited for use in educational evaluation programs for districts, schools and teachers.