1 / 62

Economie Publique II February-May 2010 Prof. A. Estache

Economie Publique II February-May 2010 Prof. A. Estache. Lecture 2 Regulating Monopolies Under information symmetry. Brief reminder. Monopoly = market failure Non convex production set because of increasing returns to scale in production (locally or constantly)

olivia-hyde
Download Presentation

Economie Publique II February-May 2010 Prof. A. Estache

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Economie Publique IIFebruary-May 2010Prof. A. Estache Lecture 2 Regulating Monopolies Under information symmetry

  2. Brief reminder • Monopoly = market failure • Non convex production set because of increasing returns to scale in production (locally or constantly) • Market failure = inefficient allocation of resources • Inefficient allocation of resource = scope for government intervention • Typical government interventions in the case of monopolies are: • 1. nationalize • 2. regulate: the focus of this course

  3. So what’s the problem with studying regulation? • What the overview last week showed is that it is difficult to come up with a single clean story on how to regulate due to heterogeneity of: • Initial conditions • Variables monitored • Economic as well as Political dimensions of regulation • Sectoral diversity • Degree and type of information asymmetry between operators and regulators • But plenty of actions in the real world to learn how regulation sometimes works in practice • Also lots of good theory work to learn to teach a few trick to practictioners! • So what this course does is to provide you with an overview of where the theory stands as well as a sense of how best practice works

  4. Here, we focus for now on Economic regulation • Although…not quite since we will really look at economic + some social regulation • Economic = price, entry, quality of product • Social= environment, safety, … • To learn more and faster…useful to distinguish between regulation with • Symmetric vs asymmetric information • Single product vs multiple products • Barriers to entry vs contestable markets • This week we focus on the simplest: • Symetric, simple, with barriers

  5. Why Monopolies again??? • What causes monopolies? • Natural monopolies • One general definition that can work for an industry is that this industry is said to be a natural monopoly if one firm can produce a desired output at a lower social cost than two or more firms (i.e deadweight loss is lower!) • SO what’s clear is that this natural monopoly is associated with a predictable cost structure • high fixed cost, extremely low constant marginal cost, declining long run average cost, MC always below AC. • Typical examples include rail, telecoms, water, electricity, ports • But also “legal” monopolies, • ie. those due to • a legal fiat; e.g. US Postal Service • a patent; e.g. a new drug • sole ownership of a resource; e.g. a toll highway • formation of a cartel; e.g. OPEC • This concept of monopoly is more about market power than about costs structures

  6. So what is “Pure Monopoly (PM)”? • A monopolized market has a single seller. • Its demand curve is the (downward sloping) market demand curve. • =>the monopolist can alter the market price by adjusting its output level.

  7. Note (1) • Common, roughly correct but misleading definition: a pure monopoly is when we have declining AC and MC curves…very restrictive • More precise definition: an industry is a natural monopoly only if its cost function is subadditive; this focus is more encompassing (i.e.having declining AC, increasing returns to scale=> subadditivity) • The cost function C(q) is subadditive at some output level if and only if: This says that the cost function is subadditive if a single firm could produce the same output for less cost=> no need to focus only on the shape of average costs to get a sense of what a monopoly is

  8. Note (2) • Subadditivity? • Costs can be subadditive even if diseconomies exist (near the total output q1+q2). • BUT in the single product case, scale economies is a sufficient condition for subadditivitity. • HOWEVER, in the multiproduct case, product-specific scale economies is not a sufficient condition. Economies of scope matter • NOTE THAT economies of scope is a necessary but not sufficient condition for subadditivity. • SO even Economies of scale and scope is no guarantee of cost subadditivity 8

  9. A monopoly can be temporary… (common in congestion related problems where demand drives the nature of the market!) D Note (3) D1 D1 D Q* diseconomies of scale Constant Returns To scale e of scale Natural Monopoly

  10. So what does subadditivity mean in practice? • It tells you when you should have a monopoly in the delivery of a service or a bundle of service and when you should allow an unbundling of the delivery of these services into two or more companies • But to see in details what it means in practice…useful to conceptualize! • Assume a cost function based on two inputs: Thus, each of i firms produce ai % of output q1 and bi % of the output q2.

  11. From a policy viewpoint what does this mean? • If the cost function is subadditive => the technology implies a natural monopoly: only allow 1 firm! • But what if we find the opposite when we measure??? • If the cost function is superadditive => the firm could save money by breaking itself up into two or more divisions. • => from a policy viewpoint, essential to see how you want to structure your industry (i.e. when you need to clear a merger request!)

  12. Economies of scale are important but so are economies of scope! • Economies of Scope? • Should we allow monopolies to produce two related products together or should we force an unbundling? • Once more: look at the costs • The formal definition • C (q1,q2) < C (q1,0) + C (0,q2) • Under Economies of Scope, it is cheaper to produce two goods together. • Generation of electricity + transmission? • Freight + passenger train transport?

  13. Let’s look at an example • Imagine you want to test the extent to which there may be a natural monopoly in cellular phone market as a result of the evolution of the sector (market and technology), • So you are concerned with: • the change of whole market size and market share of each competitors, which may affects natural monopoly status. • innovations which may alter the cost structure of this industry

  14. The Problem really boils down to one of cost analysis… • To test if you have a natural monopoly…you need to assess the cost structure of that industry • Assessment is generally done by estimating econometrically or approximating through non linear programming techniques a cost function for the sector • Note: in practice not easy to distinguish statistical errors and inefficiency when you estimate... • But there are techniques to do this…and huge volume of methodological and empirical research on this • Here is how you get to approximate your cost function

  15. So First we want to measure the Size Efficiency • Size Efficiency: Whether one company should produce all services or K companies should do from the efficiency point of view? With “x” as the input quantities and “w” as the input prices and “C” as total costs and with “y” the range of product we want to deliver (with weights on x and y) • NOTE: Economies of Scale is a special case of size efficiency modeling.

  16. Next we want to measure Economies of Scope • Economies of Scope (Orthogonal Cost Subadditivity) • is also a special case of size efficiency modeling (K=2, orthogonally constrained). Note: A: voice, B: i-mode service

  17. Then we look for data for the empirical analysis (based on case study of Tokyo)

  18. Result(1): The shrinking role of Economies of Scale in telecoms..that’s why deregulation makes sense in that sector! DoCoMo (Tokyo) DoCoMo Tohoku (northern part) • SCE is less than zero in the metropolitan area (ex. Tokyo). It means diseconomies of scale….technological revolution matters! • SCE falls around 1995 at almost of all units (due to rapid expansion of market size?) Cost efficiency SCE

  19. Result(2): …but the sustained role of economies of scope in telecoms…so still some role for a regulator! DoCoMo (Tokyo) DoCoMo Tohoku • K=1 in Tohoku and K=4 in Tokyo. (The metropolitan area is not size efficient.) Strong economies of scope exists. K Economies of scope (Size efficiency)-1

  20. Now that we know that monopolies exist… so really…what’s the social problem we need to worry about? • To answer this question: • Compare the welfare gains from trade under competition vs. under a monopoly!

  21. The efficiency of competition $/output unit The efficient output levelye satisfies p(y) = MC(y).Total gains-to-trade ismaximized. p(y) CS MC(y) p(ye) PS y ye

  22. The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit p(y) p(y*) MC(y) y y* MR(y)

  23. The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit MC(y*+1) < p(y*+1) so bothseller and buyer could gainif the (y*+1)th unit of outputwas produced. Hence the market is Pareto inefficient. p(y) CS p(y*) MC(y) PS y y* MR(y)

  24. The Inefficiency of Monopoly $/output unit Deadweight loss measures the gains-to-trade not achieved by the market. p(y) p(y*) MC(y) DWL y y* MR(y)

  25. The Inefficiency of Monopoly The monopolist produces less than the efficient quantity, making the market price exceed the efficient market price. $/output unit p(y) p(y*) MC(y) DWL p(ye) y y* ye MR(y)

  26. How much does this DWL matter to society? • If small DWL=>don’t worry too much • Empirical estimates suggest that DWL varies from 0.1 and 14% of GDP…depending on method of estimation! • But if it is reasonably big …or if it is perceived to be big (as in the case of public services)….then you need to regulate • To regulate, you need to understand the optimal strategy for a monopolist • The more its optimal strategy leads pricing to differ from marginal cost pricing…the more you need to worry ! • => look at how a monopoly picks it pricing • Easiest way to do so is analytically

  27. Useful to keep in mind how we do the simple math to figure out how a monopolist will chose prices and quantities? • Suppose that the monopolist seeks to maximize its economic profit (with the usual notation for prices and costs) • Start by asking what output level y* maximizes profit? • Then derive the price

  28. Profit-Maximization At the profit-maximizing output level y* so, for y = y*, MR - MC =0 => MR=MC or:

  29. Some more manipulation Since own-price elasticity of demand is =>

  30. =>when is a monopoly happy …and when not? Look at the drivers of its MR • SO the MR is positive IF demand curve is: • elastic (ε <-1) • And • MR is negative IF demand curve is : • -inelastic( -1<ε <0) • NOTE: 1. This elasticity depends not only on the particular demand curve but also on where on that demand curve stands (could decrease as price becomes lower) • NOTE 2: Because the demand curve is downward sloping, the monopoly must lower its prices to sell more unuts=> the MR is always<price! (>< for a competitive firm MR is always=p)

  31. =>How do you get to the monopolist optimal pricing? For a profit-maximum: MR = MC Now, suppose the monopolist’s MC is constant, at $k/output unit. which leads to

  32. So…: • …means that: • 1. We need to track what happens to the supply of y* by the monopolist as a function of the demand elasticity • 2. as e rises towards -1 the monopolist alters its output level to make the market price of its product rise • 3. a profit-maximizing monopolist always selects an output level for which market demand is own-price elastic. • 4. Most of what we will do later in using applied regulation techniques will build around these 3 variables: • What is k (costs), • what is the demand side (ε) and • how does the monopoly play with P and y to maximize profits given this costs and the demand elasticity!!

  33. NOTE: how do prices relate to market power in an industry? • Consider • And note again that at optimum, MR = MC • So substitute and rearrange… and you find: • (P-MC)/P= -1/ε • Which tells us; (i) the price-cost margin as a share of price…and (ii) that this margin ONLY depends on ε!!! • This is also known as the Lerner Index of market power • The monopoly’s price is close to its MC when high ε • Its margins is however low when ε is low! • P increasingly exceeds MC as the demand become less elastic! • For instance if ε=-100=>P=1.01MC but if ε=-2, P=2MC • => Key variable to focus on to know about troubles is ε

  34. Look at some numbers…

  35. …=> Regulating a Natural Monopoly boils down to understanding that: • A natural monopoly cannot be forced to use marginal cost pricing. • Doing so makes the firm exit, destroying both the market and any gains-to-trade. • How far the monopoly will go distancing itself from MC pricing depends on ε • If close to |1|: Huge markup => huge DWL • If much higher than |1|: Small markup => small DWL • So challenge is to pick regulatory schemes to induce the natural monopolist to produce the efficient output level without exiting.

  36. Dollars Unregulated monopoly Efficient production (requires subsidy!!!) Number of Households Served To be efficient…MC works for efficiency but financially … does not work without a subsidy! A $60 C $29 LRATC F $15 MC B MR D 50,000 100,000 85,000

  37. So what can you allow a monopoly to do? • IF Huge economies of scale (AC is always declining) ⇒natural monopoly • To have a financially viable natural monopoly⇒ need a policy to ensure service is provided at reasonable cost to users and reasonable profit to provider! • MOST OF THIS IS ABOUT PRICING TO ENSURE COST RECOVERY AND A FAIR RETURN ON ASSETS!

  38. Dollars Unregulated monopoly "Fair rate of return" production Which allows cost recovery Number of Households Served So how to come up with fair regulation of the pricing by a Natural Monopoly??? A $60 C $29 LRATC F $15 MC B MR D 50,000 100,000 85,000

  39. What kind of pricing policies would allow a monopoly to recover its costs and get a fair return on its assets? (i) MC pricing WILL NOT do it! • ⇒ unable to earn a normal ROR ⇒ Govt NEEDS TO give a subsidy (ii) Allow monopoly to recover documented costs (=>cost-plus or rate of return regulation since the + is a markup over allowed cost to allow for a return on assets allocated to the monopolist’s production) • Could allow AC pricing ⇒earn a normal ROR (Franchise bidding • Could allow provided to charge at its highest cost ( peak load pricing) • Could allow nonlinear pricing: two-part tariff, discriminatory two-part tariff, multipart tariff • Could consider Ramsey pricing (look at the elasticity of demand of the various users…) (iii) Impose a maximize average price and let the monopoly deal with the costs (i.e. set a price cap) • (vii) …or could nationalize….Public ownership of natural monopoly (iii) Could nationalize… MORE ON ALL THIS LATER IN THE COURSE!!!

  40. So how to come up with fair regulation of the pricing by a Natural Monopoly??? Dollars Unregulated monopoly "Fair rate of return" production Which allows cost recovery Number of Households Served A $60 C $29 LRATC F $15 MC B MR D 50,000 100,000 85,000 40

  41. So how to come up with fair regulation of the pricing by a Natural Monopoly??? Dollars Unregulated monopoly "Fair rate of return" production Which allows cost recovery Number of Households Served • Set this return • on assets? • *Set an average price • generating this return • * Allow for a more • complex pricing • Structure • Simply set a • maximum price • (price cap)? • Give the operator a • Subsidy/transfer A $60 C $29 LRATC F $15 MC B MR D 50,000 100,000 85,000 41

  42. What are the goals of regulation to keep in mind while trying to chose between these different instruments? • Allocative efficiency • price (of inputs and outputs…) reflect costs • optimal product variety and quality • Productive efficiency • Create an incentive to ensure that costs are minimized • dynamic as well as static • Equity/Fairness • minimize excess profit • Make sure the tariff structure is fair to all users • Financial viability…that is…fairness to the operator! • Reasonable return in relation to cost of capital! • Minimize Regulatory burden • informational requirements; monitoring • regulatory costs; lobbying

  43. …Looks like a regulator needs to achieve too many objectives … so what’s the best way to think them through? • Best way is to follow a synthetic model that allows one to address all these issues one by one • …this is what the Armstrong-Sappington paper does • So let’s focus on how they set up the regulation problem formally

  44. So what exactly does optimal regulation theory need to focus on ? • The key relevant factors are: • Obviously…the regulators objectives (usually spelled out in a sector law) • The cost of paying for subsidies if needed (and if realistic given the country’s fiscal capacity) • …or the fiscal revenue to be generated by the monopoly • The range of policy instruments available to the regulators (including subsidies) (and these are typically also spelled out in a sector law) • The regulatory bargaining power with the operators (more subtle to identify…but technically convenient to discuss in the modeling exercise) • The information needed and the asymmetry of its access between regulators and operators (useful to simulate various assumptions at this level) • The degree of benevolence of the regulator (can’t be naïve about this, simply look at how regulatory agencies are set up and staffed) • The regulator’ability to committee to long term policies (legal issue)

  45. (1) The regulator’s goals • Assume the regulator is benevolent • Assume that the regulator will focus on: (i) efficiency (DWL), (ii) equity (how to share the DWL between the users and the operators) and (iii) financial viability of the operation (how much to get the taxpayer to contribute if needed) • => Formally, to get to core of the DWL story: the regulator wants to maximize a weighted sum of • consumer/taxpayers surplus (S) (CS + subsidies or – taxes and their associated distortions) • the rent of the operator (R) (net profits in the real world…including transfers by the government to firms) W = S + αR • with α, the weight given by the regulator to the rent of the operator (it is =1 if the regulator only cares about efficiency) • with 0 ≤ α ≤1 • NOTE: If α =1: NO distributional preferences!

  46. (2) The costs of raising funds to pay for subsidize matters to the regulators too… • Λ is the cost of raising funds from the taxpayers (=social cost of public funds) • Λ≥ 0 because taxes distort production and consumption activities => create DWL • If Λ = 0, marginal cost pricing is the familiar story from traditional textbooks • Most real world models in fact assume no distortions from taxes!!! • If Λ > 0, marginal cost pricing becomes much more complex because added costs due to added distortions in the system! • What drives Λ? driven by institutions and macro conditions • About 0.3 in developed countries, >1 in LDCs • Taxpayers welfare drops with taxes paid at a rate of 1 + Λ • In the literature: • Baron and Myerson (1982) assume Λ=0 but a sets α<1 • Laffont and Tirole (1986) assume Λ >0 but sets α=1

  47. (3) The range of policy instruments available to the regulators (including subsidies) • Can the gvt afford subsidies and make direct payments • (common assumption in the literature)? • Can the regulators set tariffs? • Can the regulator influence tariff structure? • Cant the regulator influence quality? • Can the regulators impose cost benchmarking?

  48. (4) The regulatory bargaining power with the operators • The usual assumption is that the regulator has all the necessary bargaining power • Not always realistic but useful to come up with a benchmark against which the alternative of no bargaining can be assessed • It turns out that it is not too costly to assume this in terms of the realism of the model used to assess optimal regulatory policy • Usually modeled as its ability to offer a regulatory policy that the operators can decide to accept or reject • If the operator rejects it…the interaction is over!

  49. (5) The information needed and the asymmetry of its access between regulators and operators • The usual assumption is that the operators know more about demand and costs (technology, quality, efforts, …) than the regulators • => information asymmetry • Three types of informational problems • 2 are adverse selection (hidden information problems) analyzed here • on operating costs • on consumer preferences • 1 is moral hazard (hidden action problems) • On level of effort by managers to cut operating costs • Crucial issue…since optimal regulatory policy varies significantly depending on the nature and level of this information asymmetry!

  50. (6) The degree of benevolence of the regulator • What if the regulator could be “captured” by the industry it is regulating? • What if regulatory and operators could collude to get taxpayers and users to pay more than needed? • This is about explicit and implicit corruption in a sector

More Related