270 likes | 447 Views
Environmental Fiscal Reform in OECD Countries. Presentation at the conference “The Consolidation of Governance and Entrepreneurship in the Czech Republic and the European Union” Prague, 1 November 2002 by Nils Axel Braathen OECD, Environment Directorate. Outline of the presentation.
E N D
Environmental Fiscal Reform in OECD Countries Presentation at the conference “The Consolidation of Governance and Entrepreneurship in the Czech Republic and the European Union” Prague, 1 November 2002 by Nils Axel Braathen OECD, Environment Directorate
Outline of the presentation • Extent of Environmental Fiscal Reforms: • Removal of environmentally harmful subsidies • Use of environmentally related taxes • Fiscal reforms • Some experiences: • Environmental impacts • Social impacts • Economic impacts • The way forward: • Overcoming the income distribution obstacle • Overcoming the competitiveness obstacle
Removal of environmentally harmful subsidies • Very few examples of a systematic removal of subsidies due to their environmental harm. • New Zealand removed almost all subsidies • The Green Tax Commission in Norway looked at environmental impacts of many types of expenditures • More examples of reform of subsidy schemes, to make them less environmentally harmful • Agriculture • Fisheries • Economic restructuring in transition countries • Subsidy removal is now a priority area for OECD.
Use of environmentally related taxes • Detailed description in the OECD/EU database on environmentally related taxes, fees and charges. • Is available to everybody, free of charge, at • www.oecd.org/env/tax-database • Will be supplemented by another database on tradable permits, deposit-refund systems, environmentally motivated subsidies and voluntary approaches.
Environmentally Related Taxes and Green Tax Reform • All countries apply several “environmentally related taxes”. • Fuel taxes • Motor vehicle taxes • Packaging and/or waste taxes • A few countries have also engaged in (revenue neutral) Green Tax Reforms or Environmental Fiscal Reforms • Denmark, Finland, Sweden, Norway and Netherlands • United Kingdom, Germany
Revenues from environmentally related taxes in per cent of GDP
Tax revenue raised on different environmentally related tax-bases
Determining factors • Impacts of the levies on themarginalprices / costs facing the economic decision-makers. • Fixed rates per capita, etc., provide no incentives! • Price elasticities of the tax-bases, which i.a. depend on • Substitution possibilities • Short term => Technologies are given • Longer term => Impacts on technological change • The link between the tax base and the environmental problem at stake
Estimates of price elasticities • Significant differences between different studies • Time perspective • Cross-section / Time-series / Panel data / etc. • However, for many types of energy products, values in the area of -0.4 in the short run and -0.6 in the long run have been found. • Hence, a 10% price increase could reduce use of energy products by about 6% in the long term.
Income distribution • There are some indications that certain environmentally related taxes can have a slight negative impact on low-income households. • However, little empirical evidence is available. • The improvements in environmental quality should also be taken into account. • Poor people often live in areas that are particularly affected by pollution.
Employment impacts • There is no indication that Environmental Fiscal Reforms have significant negative impacts on total employment. • Is there also a “double dividend”? • Recent economic theory make it not seem likely. • Still, most tax reforms seek to reduce unemployment. • Very difficult to tell from – mostly lacking – ex post empirical evaluations whether this was achieved. • Disentangling problems – other factors also impact on employment. • What would otherwise have happened? • Some available studies are too partial in the approach.
Sectoral Competitiveness • We have not found significant negative competitiveness impacts for any sector from current environmentally related taxes. • But, this is probably largely due to numerous mitigation measures, such as: • Complete exemptions for certain products or sectors • Reduced tax rates for certain products or sectors • Tax refunds for certain products or sectors • Upper ceilings on the tax payments in some sectors • Recycling of revenues to certain taxpayers
Economic costs of environmental policies • The flip-side of the coin (the exemptions) is that the burden on other sectors increases – if a given environmental target is to be reached. • The marginal abatement costs are not equalised between different polluters. • Hence, total economic costs of environmental policy are higher than necessary. • However, there are no indications that the total abatement costs are “excessive” at present.
Expenditure on domestic fuels in EU countries (1988) Source: Presentation made by Terry Barker at EEB’s annual conference, Brussels, 10 October 2002
A Czech case • I'm NOT an expert on the Czech situation! • However, concern for the impacts on low-income households seems to explain the full refund given in taxes on fuel when the fuel is used to produce heat. • This lowers the incentives for energy efficiency improvements and thus leads to higher emissions. • Better to address the concerns by modest increases in pensions, some subsidies for housing insulation, “non-wasteable tax credits”, etc?
Case study: the steel sector • Sectoral competitiveness impacts is a real issue. • A model-based simulation of a 25$ per tonne CO2 tax. • An OECD-wide carbon tax would reduce OECD steel production -- and related CO2 emissions -- significantly. • Also global CO2 emissions would decrease. • The production reduction would be much greater for integrated mills (BOF) than for scrap-based mills (EAF). • Unilateral policies by single regions or countries may lead to quite dramatic cut-backs in the production of BOF steel, because there would be smaller opportunities to shift the tax burden over to suppliers or customers.
Case study: the steel sector (continued) • Most of the emissions in the steel industry are related to energy consumption. To exempt process-related emissions from a carbon tax would therefore not imply a big relief in the tax burden of BOF steel producers. • If the tax revenues were recycled back to the steel industry as an output subsidy, the decline in OECD steel production would be quite small. There could, however, be a significant restructuring towards the relatively clean EAF steel making. • Revenue recycling could, nevertheless, reduce global emission reductions.
Possible policy approaches • Integrate EFR with broader fiscal reforms. • Phase-out current rebates and exemptions gradually. • Use a two-tier rate structure, rather than full exemptions, for internationally exposed sectors. • Announce new taxes and tax rate increases well in advance. • Impose eventually full tax rates on industry, but channel part of the revenues back in such a way that marginal abatement incentives are maintained -- e.g. the Swedish NOx charge. • Work for increased international co-operation.
Current OECD work • The impacts on sectoral competitiveness and income distribution are at the core of OECD’s current work on environmentally related taxes. • We are undertaking a quantification of environmentally harmful subsidies. • We encourage greater international co-operation.