300 likes | 363 Views
Research and Development. Introduction. Technical progress is the source of rising living standards over time Introduces new concept of efficiency
E N D
Research and Development Chapter 22: Research and Development
Introduction • Technical progress is the source of rising living standards over time • Introduces new concept of efficiency • Static efficiency—traditional allocation of resources to produce existing goods and services so as to maximize surplus and minimize deadweight loss • Dynamic efficiency—creation of new goods and services to raise potential surplus over time Chapter 22: Research and Development
Introduction 2 • Schumpeterian hypotheses (conflict between static and dynamic efficiency) • Concentrated industries do more research and development of new goods and services, i.e., are more dynamically efficient, than competitively structured industries • Large firms do more research & development than small firms Chapter 22: Research and Development
A Taxonomy of Innovations Product versus Process Innovations • Product Innovations refer to the creation of new goods and new services, e.g., DVD’s, PDA’s, and cell phones • Process Innovations refer to the development of new technologies for producing goods or new ways of delivering services, e.g., robotics and CAD/CAM technology • We mainly focus on process or cost-savings innovations but the lines of distinction are blurred—a new product can be the means of implementing a new process Chapter 22: Research and Development
A Taxonomy of Innovations 2 Drastic versus Non-Drastic Innovations • Process innovations have two further categories • Drastic innovations have such great cost savings that they permit the innovator to price as an unconstrained monopolist • Non-drastic innovations give the innovator a cost adavantage but not unconstrained monopoly power Chapter 22: Research and Development
Drastic versus Non-Drastic Innovations • Suppose that demand is given by: P = 120 – Q and all firms have constant marginal cost of c = $80 • Let one firm have innovation that lowers cost to cM = $20 • This is a Drastic innovation. Why? • Marginal Revenue curve for monopolist is: MR= 120 – 2Q • If cM = $20, optimal monopoly output is: QM = 70 and PM= $70 • Innovator can charge optimal monopoly price ($70) and still undercut rivals whose unit cost is $80 Chapter 22: Research and Development
Drastic versus Non-Drastic Innovations 2 • Now consider the case if cost fell only to $60, innovation is Non-drastic • Marginal Revenue curve again is: MR = 120 = 2Q • Optimal Monopoly output and price: QM = 30; PM = $90 • However, innovator cannot charge $90 because rivals have unit cost of $80 and could under price it • Innovator cannot act as an unconstrained monopolist • Best innovator can do is to set price of $80 (or just under) and supply all 40 units demanded. Chapter 22: Research and Development
NonDrastic Innovation: QM < QC so innovator cannot charge monopoly price PMbecause rivals can undercut that price Drastic Innovation: QM > QC so innovator can charge monopoly price PMwithout constraint Drastic vs. Non-Drastic Innovations 3 Innovation is drastic if monopoly output QMat MR = new marginal c’ exceeds the competitive output QC at old marginal cost c $/unit = p $/unit = p PM c c PM c’ Demand Demand c’ MR MR Quantity Quantity QC QM QM QC Chapter 22: Research and Development
Innovation and Market Structure • Arrow’s (1962) analysis— • Innovative activity likely to be too little because innovators consider only monopoly profit that the innovation brings and not the additional consumer surplus • Monopoly provides less incentive to innovate that competitive industry because of the Replacement Effect • Assume demand is: P= 120 – Q; MC= $80. Q is initially 40. Innovator lowers cost to $60 and can sell all 40 units at P = $80. • Profit Gain is $800–Less than Social Gain Initial Surplus is Yellow Triangle--Social Gains from Innovation are Areas A ($800) and B ($200) But Innovator Only Considers Profit Area A ($800) $/unit 120 80 A B 60 Quantity 40 60 120 Chapter 22: Research and Development
Innovation and Market Structure 2 • Now consider innovation when market structure is monopoly • Initially, the monopolist produces where MC = MR = $80 at Q = 20 and P = $100, and earns profit (Area C) of $400 • Innovation allows monopolist to produce where MC = MR = $60 at Q= 30 and P = $90 and earn profit of $900 • But this is a gain of only $500 over initial profit due to Replacement Effect—new profits destroy old profits $/unit Monopolist Initially Earns Profit C—With Innovation it Earns Profit A—Net Profit Gain is Area A – Area C Which is Less than the Gain to a Competitive Firm 120 100 C 90 A 80 60 Demand MR 20 30 60 120 Quantity Chapter 22: Research and Development
Innovation and Market Structure 3 • Preserving Monopoly Profit--the Efficiency Effect • Previous Result would be different if monopolist had to worry about entrant using innovation • Assume Cournot competition and that entrant can only enter if it has lower cost, i.e., if it uses the innovation • If Monopolist uses innovation, entrant cannot enter and monopolist earns $900 in profit • If Monopolist does not use innovation, entrant can enter as low-cost firm in a duopoly • Entrant earns profit of $711 • Incumbent earns profit of $44 • Gain from innovation now is no longer $900 - $400 = $500 but $900 - $44 = $856 • Monopolist always has more to gain from innovation than does entrant—this is the Efficiency Effect Chapter 22: Research and Development
Competition and Innovation • The incumbent/entrant model just discussed seems closer in spirit to Schumpeter’s ideas than Arrow’s analysis. • Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980) come even closer by directly embedding innovation in a model of Cournot competition • Profit for each firm: i = P(Q) – c(xi)qi – xi • Here, firm’s unit cost falls as the firm engages in R&D activity • What is the equilibrium? • Define x* as the optimal R&D level of each firm • From Chapter 9, we know that • But with n symmetric firms si = 1/n, So we have Output Condition Chapter 22: Research and Development
Competition and Innovation 2 • How much should x* be? • The usual marginal calculations apply. Every increase in x costs $1. The benefit is the cost reduction this brings, c(x)/x, times the number of units q* to which this cost reduction will apply R&D Condition – Both the Output Condition and the R&D Condition must hold simultaneously in any equilibrium – One obvious implication of the R&D Condition is that the R& D effort of any one firm will fall as the number of n firms increases because this will decrease the output of each firm Chapter 22: Research and Development
Competition and Innovation 3 • Making nendogenous means allowing firms to enter until they no longer have an incentive to do so • This will occur when firms earn zero profit after allowing for R&D costs. Defining n* as the equilibrium number of firms, the Output Condition then implies: • Substitution into the R&D Condition then yields: Industry R&D as Share of Sales • Industry R&D effort declines as n* rise, i.e., as industry becomes less concentrated—fairly strong theoretical support for Schumpeterian Hypothesis Chapter 22: Research and Development
Competition and Innovation 4 • But empirical support for Schumpeterian view is mixed • Need to control for science-based sectors (e.g., chemicals, pharmaceuticals, and electronics) and non-technology based sectors (e.g., restaurants and hair stylists)—R&D much more likely in science-based sectors regardless of firm size • Need also to distinguish between R&D expenditures and true innovations. Common finding [e.g., Cohen and Klepper (1996)], is that large firms do somewhat more R&D but achieve less real innovative breakthroughs—e.g., Apple produced the first PC • Market structure is endogenous. Innovations might create industry giants (e.g., Alcoa) not the other way around. • Bottom Line: Validity of Schumpeterian hypotheses is still undetermined Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D • Technological break-throughs by one firm often “spill over’ to other firms • Spillover is unlikely to be complete but likely to arise to some extent • We can model this in the Dasgupta Stiglitz world by now writing a firm’s unit cost as a function of both its own and its rival’s R&D • c1 = c – x1 - x2 • c2 = c – x2 - x1 • To obtain solution, need also to assume that R&D is subject to diminishing returns, e.g., r(x) = x2/2. Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 2 • In this setting, response of firm 1’s R&D to firm 2’s R&D depends on size of spillover term . • When is small, R&D expenditures are strategic substitutes—the more firm 1 does the less firm 2 will do • When is large, R&D expenditures are strategic complements—the more firm 1 does the more firm 2 will do • However, determination of whether R&D efforts are strategic substitutes or strategic complements is not sufficient to determine what happens when there are spillovers Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 3 • Let Demand be given by: P = A – BQ • Let ci = c – xi– xj; • Each firm now chooses both production qiand research intensity xi • General Solution is: • To illustrate, consider two cases • – First case: Low Spillovers; = 0.25 • – Second case: High Spillovers; = 0.75 Chapter 22: Research and Development
Nash Equilibrium is for both firms to choose the high level of research intensity (x = 10). Why? When degree of spillovers is small, firm know that its rival can do R&D knowing that it will get most of the benefits. Since this would advantage the rival, each firm tries to avoid being left behind by doing lots of R&D itself. R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 4 The Pay-Off Matrix for = 0.25 Firm 1 Low Research Intensity High Research Intensity Low Research Intensity $107.31, $107.31 $100.54, $110.50 Firm 2 High Research Intensity $110.50, $100.54 $103.13, $103.13 Chapter 22: Research and Development
Nash Equilibrium is for both firms to choose the low level of research intensity (x = 7.5). Why? When degree of spillovers is large, a firm knows that it will benefit from technical advance of its rival even if it doesn’t do any R&D itself. So, each firm tries to free-ride off its rival and each does little R&D itself. R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 5 The Pay-Off Matrix for = 0.75 Firm 1 Low Research Intensity High Research Intensity Low Research Intensity $128.67, $128.671, $136.13, $125.78 Firm 2 High Research Intensity $125.78, $136.13 $133.68, $133.68 Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 6 • MORAL of the foregoing analysis is that the Outcome of non-cooperative R&D spending depends critically on the extent of spillovers. • What if R&D spending is cooperative? • R&D cooperation can take two forms: • 1. Do R&D independently but choose x1 and x2 jointly to maximize combined profits, given competition in product market is maintained. • 2. Do R&D together as one firm, e.g, form a Research Joint Venture. That is, effectively operate as though the degree of spillovers is = 1, again though, continue to maintain product market competition. • The two types have very different implications. Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 7 • Consider first the case of coordinated but not centralized R&D using our generalized demand and cost equations • Total R&D spending now rises unambiguously as increases. • To see this note that given our earlier demand and cost assumptions, and given the fact that x1 and x2 are chosen to maximize joint profits, the optimal values for x1 and x2 are: Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 8 • This solution for the profit-maximizing research level under cooperation is unambiguously increasing in but this is a good news/bad news story. • The good news is that for the high spillover case ( >1), the free- riding problem is no longer an issue and firms now do more R&D • The bad news is that for the low spillover case ( < 1), there is no longer a fear of being left behind by one’s rival. So in this case firms do less R&D which means costs (and consumer prices) are higher than without cooperation. Chapter 22: Research and Development
R&D Spillovers and Cooperative R&D 9 • What about a Research Joint Venture? • As noted, this effectively changes to 1. • For our demand and cost equations, it can be shown that: – This is clearly more R&D than occurred with simple coordination for any given value of – As a result, it leads to lower costs and more output to the benefit of consumers – Profits are also higher. Thus, in the presence of spillovers, Research Joint Ventures are unambiguously beneficial. – The only trick is to make sure that cooperation is limited to research and does not extend to other dimensions of competition Chapter 22: Research and Development
Empirical Application: International Spillovers in R&D • Perhaps we can get evidence on the extent of R&D spillovers by looking at technology spillovers between the same industry across different countries • This is the strategy employed by Keller (2002) • Consider output in industry i and country c • ln Qci = (1 – )n Kci+ ln Lci • Or: Total Factor Productivity in country c and industry i is: • TFPci = ln Qci – (1 – )n Kci+ ln Lci Chapter 22: Research and Development
Empirical Application: International Spillovers in R&D 2 • Using bars to denote average industry ilevels across the entire sample, Keller measures the relative factor productivity in industry icountry cthen as follows: • This equation measures relative productivity at a point in time. • Keller measures Fcifor each of 12 industries in 14 countries over the years 1970 to 1995. • He thus has productivity observations that vary across space and time Fcit • He seeks to explain the observed changes in productivity in each industry/contribution over time on the basis of domestic and foreign R&D Chapter 22: Research and Development
Empirical Application: International Spillovers in R&D 3 • Keller divides his 14 countries into two groups • Engines of technical change: France, Germany, Japan, UK and US • Nine Others: Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain, and Sweden • He asks how relative factor productivity in industries in each of the nine depends on their own R&D and the R&D in the 5 engines of technical change countries, the G5 • In particular, Keller supposes that the relevant technical base for any of the 12 industries in any of the nine countries is a function of its own R&D and R&D in the G5 Chapter 22: Research and Development
Empirical Application: International Spillovers in R&D 4 • Let Scit be the amount of R&D done up to year t in country c and industry i. • Keller says that this contributes to a nation’s relative factor productivity according to the following equation • Here measures the productivity impact of (the log) of all R&D relevant to the domestic industry’s relative productivity • That relevant R&D is comprised of two parts • Domestic R&D Scit contributes directly to productivity • R&D in the G5 contributes less directly if is less than one and the effect is weaker for countries farther away as measured by distance D if is positive Chapter 22: Research and Development
Empirical Application: International Spillovers in R&D 5 • Keller (2002) uses nonlinear estimation techniques to estimate the parameters , , and jointly after controlling for country-specific and time-specific effects. His basic results areCoefficient Estimate Std. Error 0.078 (0.013) 1.005 (0.239) 0.843 (0.059) • All these effects are statistically significant. • Own country R&D raises productivity by roughly 7.8 percent if there is no G5 R&D • G5 R&D is 84.3 percent of domestic R&D but the 1.005 value for implies that his effect declines rapidly as the G5 country is farther away and disappears entirely once that distance reaches 400 miles • However, once Keller allows for differential impacts depending on which G5 country does the R&D the spillover lasts up to 1200 miles. Such extensive spillovers between nations suggests that R&D spillovers between firms are probably significant Chapter 22: Research and Development