1 / 24

The Social Satisfaction: a Fairness Theory about Income Distribution with Applications in China

The Social Satisfaction: a Fairness Theory about Income Distribution with Applications in China Ouyang Kui Institute of Quantitative & Technical Economics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences. 1 Introduction. Economic development, income growth and social welfare

tammy
Download Presentation

The Social Satisfaction: a Fairness Theory about Income Distribution with Applications in China

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Social Satisfaction: a Fairness Theory about Income Distribution withApplications in China OuyangKui Institute of Quantitative & Technical Economics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences

  2. 1 Introduction • Economic development, income growth and social welfare • The Dalton-Atkinson’s approach (Dalton, 1920; Atkinson, 1970) • The choice of SWFs and the choice of utility functions • The dictatorship conclusion(d’Aspremont & Gevers, 1977) and Arrow’s impossibility theorem (Arrow, 1963) • The Nash SWF(Nash, 1950) • Revealed preferences and subjective satisfaction: OrdinalismvsCardinalism (Mandler,2006) • The axiomatic characterization of the measure of income distribution

  3. 2 The Nash SWF: A differentialequation approach • Definition 2.1 A SWF is homogeneous of degree k: • Definition 2.2 A SWF is symmetrically differentiable:

  4. Theorem 2.3 The only homogeneous, symmetrically differentiable SWF is the linear power transformation of Nash SWF:

  5. 3 The Social Satisfaction • 3.1 The SF: a fuzzy measure of utility Definition 3.1The individual satisfaction function (SF): S: RN→[0,1]. • 3.2 The SSF: a normative on SWF Definition 3.2.1 The SWFW(S1, …, SN) is a social satisfaction function (SSF) if we have Theorem 3.2.2 The unique homogeneous and symmetrically differentiable SSF is the geometric average of individual SFs.

  6. 3.3 The invariance properties of SWF

  7. 4 Fairness and equality in income distribution • 4.1 The Nash bargaining problem: The Nashsolution to the bargaining problem (impartiality):

  8. 4.2 The general form of satisfactionfunction: • 4.3 The social satisfaction index(SSI)of income distribution The Nash solution:

  9. 4.4Be equal of welfare or income? Inequality in different solutions • The Egalitarian SSF: The Egalitarian solution: • The Nash SSF: The Nash solution: • The Utilitarian SSF: The Utilitarian solution:

  10. Inequality in different solutions

  11. 5 The axiomatic characterization ofthe SSI of income distribution • Theorem 5.1 If for all x ∈ R, the SF is second-order differentiable, S(0) = 0, S(+∞) = 1, then we have • Definition 5.2 A SF has logarithmic constant elasticity if for all we have

  12. Theorem 5.3 A SF has logarithmic constant elasticity if and only if it can be generated from If all SFs have logarithmic constant elasticity, then the SSI can be expressed as: • Property 5.4 (Transfers principle) Y is obtained from X and for some i and j, (a)Si(xi)<Sj(xj); (b) xi-yi=yj-xj>0; (c) xk=yk for all k≠i,j, we have: (1)If xi<xj, then W(X) > W(Y); (2)More generally, if yi<yj, then W(X) > W(Y).

  13. Property 5.5 (Independent of income units) If W(Y) = W(X), then for t > 0, W(tY) = W(tX). • Property 5.6 (Replication principle) If a society N(Y, Sn×m) is a replication of another society M(X, Sm), Y=Xn, X=xm, then W(X) = W(Y). • Property 5.7 (Geometric Decomposability) In a society of N agents, for N = n + m, then Generally, for N =n1+ …+nm, then we have

  14. If we set for all i, i.e. the SSI is symmetric, then the SSI can be defined as: • Property 5.8 (Symmetry) If Y is obtained from X by a permutation of incomes, then W(Y) = W(X). • Property 5.9 (Pigou-Dalton transfers principle) If is obtained from such that for some i and j, (a)xi<xj; (b) xi-yi=yj-xj>0; (c) xk=yk for all k≠i,j, then W(Y) > W(X).

  15. Property 5.10 (Population principle) If Y is a replication of X, then W(X) = W(Y). • Property 5.11 (Homogeneity) If Y = tX, t>0, then W(Y) = W(X) if we set • Theorem5.12 Let W(xi)=Si(xi). Then the unique index W of income distribution satisfies the geometric decomposability (Property 5.7) for all N ≥1 is

  16. 6 A simpleapplication inChina • Does the Chinese Reform and Open Policy practice generate a fair income distribution? • How much had Chinese people been satisfied by the great increase in national income in the past several decades?

  17. Figure 1 Impartial regional income distribution

  18. Figure 2 Unfair income distributions between urban and rural

  19. Inspired by supported evidences for that more income brings greater satisfaction among income groups at a point in life and a cohort’s satisfaction remains constant throughout the life span (Easterlin, 2001), we thus construct the following SF and SSI:

  20. Table Ⅱ SSI in China

  21. Figure 3 Inequality of SSI

  22. 7 Conclusions • First, the uniqueness of homogenous and symmetrically differentiable SSF shows that economists might be more unified about the analytic form of SWF. • Second, the concept of social satisfaction is similar to individual satisfaction as well as the social welfare and the individual utility. • Another fact is that the equality on welfare does not necessarily mean the equality on income distribution. • In addition, the evidence from China shows that the social welfare may not increase even if the social income level increases a lot. • Finally, an important but unresolved question is that whether the impartial income distribution can lead to an equal distribution of income or satisfaction. After all, the fairness concept should be about both impartiality and equality.

  23. Appendices • A Proof of theorem 2.3 • B Proof of theorem 5.1 • C Proof of theorem 5.3 • D Original datasets

  24. References • Arrow, K.J.: Social choice and individual values, 2d ed. New York: Wiley (1963). • d’Aspremont, C., Gevers, L.: Equity and the informational basis of collective choice. Review of Economic Studies 44, 199-209 (1977) • Atkinson, A.B.: On the measure of inequality, Journal of Economic Theory 2, 244-263 (1970) • Bergson, A.: A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economies. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52, 310-334 (1938) • Dalton, H.: The measurement of the inequality of incomes, Quarterly Journal of Economics 30, 348-361 (1920) • Dasgupta, P., Sen, A., Starrett, D.: Notes on the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 6, 180-187 (1973) • Dubins, L.E., Spanier, E.H.: How to cut a cake fairly. The American Mathematical Monthly 68, 1-17 (1961) • Easterlin, R.A.: Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. The Economic Journal 111, 465-484 (2001) • Foster, J.E.: An axiomatic characterization of the Theil measure of income inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 31, 105-121(1983) • Kahneman, D., Krueger, A.B.: Developments on the measurement of subjective well-being. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 20, 3-23(2006) • Mandler, M.: Cardinality versus ordinality: a suggested compromise. The American Economic Review 96, 1114-1136 (2006) • Nash, J.F.: The bargaining problem. Econometrica18, 155-162 (1950) • Pigou, A.C.: Wealth and welfare. Macmillan Co., London (1912) • Samuelson, P.: Foundations of economic analysis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Mass. (1947) • Samuelson, P.: The problem of integrability in utility theory. Economica17, 355-385 (1950)

More Related