340 likes | 424 Views
Are labour markets polarising?. Craig Holmes and Ken Mayhew. Department of Education, University of Oxford May 10 th 2010. Polarisation, segmentation and mobility. Routinisation hypothesis (Autor, Levy and Murnane, 2003): Price of computer capital has fallen since late 1970s
E N D
Are labour markets polarising? Craig Holmes and Ken Mayhew Department of Education, University of Oxford May 10th 2010
Polarisation, segmentation and mobility • Routinisation hypothesis (Autor, Levy and Murnane, 2003): • Price of computer capital has fallen since late 1970s • Computer capital replaces labour engaged in routine tasks • Non-routine tasks may be complementary to computer capital (e.g. management, skilled professionals) • Result: growth in non-routine occupations due to changes in demand (complementarities) and supply (displaced routine workers) • Polarisation hypothesis (Goos and Manning, 2007) • Routine occupations found in middle of income distribution • Non-routine occupations found at top and bottom of distribution • Managers, skilled professionals at the top • Non-routine ‘service’ occupations at the bottom e.g. hairdressers, cleaners
Polarisation, segmentation and mobility • Labour market segmentation theory developed as a departure from traditional models of labour supply and demand in the 1960s and 1970s • LMS suggests it is possible to identify parts of the labour market between which mobility is severely or entirely restricted • These restrictions are related to factors other than individual skills or abilities • Dual market: primary and secondary sector distinguished by wages, security, prospects for promotion and training investment • Initial employment matters workers becoming ‘trapped’
Polarisation, segmentation and mobility • Obvious overlap between the primary and secondary segments in LMS and growth occupations in polarisation hypothesis • Individuals tend to move short distances within the labour market in terms of job quality. Declining middling occupations reduces options for transitory upward steps to better occupations. • Hence, a “hollowed-out” labour market could create two segments with limited mobility between them.
Job polarisation in the UK: an assessment • Holmes, (2010), SKOPE research paper no. 90 • Need to understand the ways the polarisation phenomena has or has not manifested within a dataset that can be used for analysing working life mobility • Looks at single cohort from National Child Development Study between 1981 (aged 23) and 2004 (aged 46). • Replicates the Goos and Manning methodology for our NCDS dataset • Finds growth in high wage and low wage occupations, decline in mid-range occupations, proxied by 1981 wage • Evidence of routinisation driven employment changes
Job polarisation in the UK: an assessment • Change in employment share of wage deciles.
Job polarisation in the UK: an assessment • Resulting wage distributions are important • Absent of other effects, a polarising labour force should be observed as in the diagram below:
Job polarisation in the UK: an assessment • Wage distributions exhibit little evidence of polarisation • Most jobs still fall in the middle of wage distribution
Job polarisation in the UK: an assessment • How can these two observations be reconciled? • Existing evidence relies on a strong assumption that wage structures have remained constant • Changing wage structures may have led to a new type of middling occupation. • Assumption used throughout literature (Autor, Katz and Kearney, 2006, for US; Spitz-Oener, 2006, for Germany) • Need a new methodology to support polarisation hypothesis • Continue to look at wage distributions • Resulting wages, rather than distribution of jobs, matter • Proxy for job quality?
Wage distributions • Large literature on wage distributions, especially focusing on inequality • Prasad (2002), UK 1975-1999: • faster growing upper wage inequality than lower wage inequality • U-shaped wage growth – lowest earning occupations had highest growth rate between 1975-80 • Machin and Van Reenen (2007), UK & USA 1979-2004: • 1980s – U-shaped wage growth in UK, monotonic wage growth in USA • 1990s – U-shaped wage growth in USA • Lower wage inequality constant or reducing over time period • Autor, Katz and Kearney, (2006), USA, 1973-2004: • Patterns of inequality can be explained by “polarisation” – specifically, the wage effects of change in demand.
Wage distributions • Prasad (2002) also finds within-group inequality explains 75% of all changes in inequality
Wage distributions • Biggest issue with analysing changing distributions is separating out all effects: • Wage determination process: • yt = gt(x) • Wage effects come through changes to changes to g • Returns to education, occupational premia, union premia, returns to experience, discrimination • Composition effects come through changes to x • Level of education, occupational structure, union membership, demographics • Polarisation is a composition effect (Goos and Manning), which leads to a wage effect (Autor, Katz and Kearney)
Wage distributions • Polarisation vs. SBTC wage growth ln wage ln wage
A quantile regression approach • Number of approaches to measuring changing distributions, usually involving some form of quantile regression: • Typical OLS regression computes mean values conditional on explanatory variables • Conditional quantile regressions compute quantiles of a distribution conditional on explanatory variables • However, we need to look at unconditional distributions (i.e. conditional distributions integrated over all explanatory variables) • Firpo, Fortin and Lemieux (2007) – henceforth FFL – supply an appropriate methodology • Individual contribution of covariates to wage and composition effects
A quantile regression approach • Data: • N observations, N0 from initial distribution, N1 from final distribution • Ti = 1 if from final distribution, i = 1,...,N. Pr(Ti) = p • Yi and Xi observed • Yi = Yi0 (1 – Ti) + Yi1 Ti where Yit = gt(Xi, ei), t = 0,1 • Data can be reweighted to give initial, final and (unobserved) counterfactual distributions. • Counterfactual is wage distribution that would have arisen given initial wage determination process but final explanatory variables • FC (y) = Pr (Y0 <y | T = 1)
A quantile regression approach • Reweighting: • where p(x) = Pr (T=1 | X = x)
A quantile regression approach • FFL show that this requires that: • Errors must be independent of T • There must be overlap of covariates – 0 < p(x) < 1 • Calculate p(x) using logistical regression • This counterfactual can be used to decompose wage and composition effects of a distributional statistic: • Give statistic represented by functional v(F) – e.g. percentile, Gini co-efficient etc. • Δv(F)= (v(F1) - v(Fc)) + v(Fc) - v(F1) Δv(F)=ΔvW + ΔvC
A quantile regression approach • FFL’s second contribution is to find a linear approximation of each distributional functional, conditional on the explanatory variables • An influence function, IF, of v(F) is a measure of sensitivity to outliers, where E(IF) = 0 • A recentered influence function, RIF = v(F) + IF, so E(RIF) = v(F) • RIF’s can be conditional on X • Assume a linear projection of RIF onto X: • where j = {0, C, 1}
A quantile regression approach • FFL show that: • ΔvW = E(X|T=1) (γ1 – γC) • ΔvC = E(X|T=1) γC - E(X|T=0) γ0 • Moreover, if expectation of RIF is linear, γC = γ0. • This is a more general case of the Blinder-Oaxaca decomposition, where v(F) is the mean. • Our approach looks at 10th, 50th and 90th percentile • v(F) = qτ = inf(y|F(y)<τ), τ = {.1,.5..9} RIF= v(F) + (τ - I(y< q) j = {0,C,1) fj(qτ) • Estimate fi(qτ) using kernel density methods
Data • Family Expenditure Survey • Household expenditure and income 1957-2001 • Two surveys for sample: 1987 and 2001 • Covers period of routinisation • Cross-sectional data, rather than longitudinal • Variables: • Age finished full-time education – convert this into dummies for degree, post-compulsory education and high school education • Experience, sex, union membership • No variables on racial background. • Not used at present: marital status, industry
Data • The 1987 survey first to include data on occupation through socio-economic groups. • Broad groups; captures some of the pattern of routinisation
Data • Creates larger occupational groups: • Seven groups • Corresponds to high skill non-routine, routine and low-skill non-routine occupations
Data • Descriptive statistics:
Results: individual contributions • Decomposition by wage and composition
Results: individual contributions • Low wage jobs: • Large impact of declining unionisation • Small impact of occupational change • No evidence of increasing wage returns for low skill non-routine occupations • Expansion of higher education has impact even on low wage jobs • Majority of change explained by increasing returns to education, especially high school • Declining gender pay gap • Large negative impact from constant term – policy environment? Would expect a positive effect from national minimum wage
Results: individual contributions • Middling jobs: • Again, large impact of declining unionisation • Occupational composition effects through growth of managerial and intermediate occupations and decline of manual routine occupations • Education (levels, rather than returns) has important effect • Largest effect of declining gender pay gap
Results: individual contributions • High wage jobs: • Insignificant effect of unions, service and manual routine occupations • Polarisation of employment in managerial occupations, as expected • Wage growth effects by occupations, rather than education • Compare wage growth effects for high skill occupations to median group – increased demand for high skill non-routine leads to higher wages only for “best” workers. • Effect of education through composition rather than wage effects. Education composition effects larger than occupational composition effects • All percentiles had large positive effects from increasing returns to experience – proxy for informal training, learning by doing etc.
Comparison with other studies • FFL similarly find institutional factors, such as union membership, and education has a much stronger impact of distributions than occupations and industries • Important role for union membership and gender pay gap in our results • Composition effects from occupations fit in with Goos and Manning predictions (although much less so for low wage occupations). However, these effects often outweighed by other composition and wage effects. • Antonczyk, DeLeire and Fitzenberger (2010) – polarisation of wages is a US phenomena – our results support this.
Conclusion • Polarisation of employment has played some role in changing wage distributions, however: • Our results suggest this is mostly for high skill non-routine occupations • The growth of these occupations also impacts the middle of the distribution • Other compositional effects (e.g. education and union membership) and other wage effects (e.g. gender pay, returns to education and experience) often dwarf polarisation effects. • “Polarisation“ of wages not found at low end when controlling for education • Evidence of new type of middling occupation
Extensions and further work • FES is relatively small sample, with limited data on occupations and omits period 1975-1986 • Repeat using alternative, larger dataset • Labour Force Survey has no wage data until 1994 • New Earnings Survey has no data on education. • Need to test for misspecification of RIF regressions. • Implications for segmentation: • More complicated picture of labour market than initial hypothesis • Middle of distribution is not disappearing or “hollowing out” in the way suggested by literature • Routinisation may still have implications for mobility – role of education, informal learning and possible career paths