380 likes | 507 Views
Portfolio Optimization with Spectral Measures of Risk Carlo Acerbi and Prospero Simonetti. Torino – January 30, 2003. Outline of the talk. What is a Spectral Measure of Risk ? Coherency and Convexity Minimization of Expected Shortfall (ES) Minimization of Spectral Measures
E N D
Portfolio Optimization with Spectral Measures of Risk Carlo Acerbi and Prospero Simonetti Torino – January 30, 2003
Outline of the talk • What is a Spectral Measure of Risk ? • Coherency and Convexity • Minimization of Expected Shortfall (ES) • Minimization of Spectral Measures • Risks and Rewards: are they really two orthogonal dimensions ?
Part 1: What is a Spectral Measure of Risk ?
Coherent Measures of Risk In “Coherent measures of Risk” (Artzner et al. Mathematical Finance, July 1999)a set of axioms was proposed as the key properties to be satisfied by any “coherent measure of risk”. (Monotonicity) ifthen (Positive Homogeneity) ifthen (Translational Invariance) (Subadditivity)
The VaR vs ES debate Value at Risk (for a chosen x% confidence level and time horizon) is defined as “The VaRof a portfolio is theminimum lossthat a portfolio can suffer in the x% worst cases” Expected Shortfall is defined as: “The ESof a portfolio is theaverage lossthat a portfolio can suffer in the x% worst cases” The debate arises since ES, turns out to be a Coherent Measure of Risk while VaR is well known to be a not-Coherent Measure of Risk VaR = the best of worst cases ES = the average of worst cases
Spectral Measures of Risk: Let’s consider the class of Spectral Measures of Risk defined as where the ”Risk Spectrum” is an arbitrary real function on [0,1] They include in particular: ES with: Heavyside Step Function VaR with: Dirac Delta Function
Spectral Measures of Risk • Theorem: the Spectral Measure of Risk • Is coherent if and only if its Risk Spectrum satisfies • is positive • is decreasing
Worst cases Best cases The “Risk Aversion Function” (p) Any admissible (p) represents a possible legitimate rational attitude toward risk A rational investor may express her own subjective risk aversion through her own subjective(p) which in turns give her own spectral measure M (p): Risk Aversion Function It may thought of as a function which “weights” all cases from the worst to the best
Expected Shortfall: Step function • positive • decreasing Value at Risk: Spike function • positive • not decreasing not coherent Risk Aversion Function (p) for ES and VaR
Ordered statistics (= data sorted from worst to best) Discretized function Estimating Spectral Measures of Risk It can be shown that any spectral measure has the following consistent estimator:
Part 2: Coherency and Convexity
Convexity of the “Risk Surface” Absence of local minima / Existence of a unique global minimum Coherency and Convexity in short Coherency of the Risk Measure
An interesting prototype portfolio Consider a portfolio made of n risky bonds all of which have a 2% default probability and suppose for simplicity that all the default probabilities are independent of one another. Portfolio = { 100 Euro invested in n independent identical distributed Bonds } Bond payoff = Nominal (or 0 with probability 2%) Question: let’s choose n in such a way to minimize the risk of the portfolio Let’s try to answer this question with a 5% VaR, ES and TCE (= ES (old)) with a time horizon equal to the maturity of the bond.
“risk” versus number of bonds in the portfolio The surface of risk of ES has a single global minimum at n= and no fake local minima. ES just tell us: “buy more bonds you can” VaR and TCE suggest us NOT TO BUY the 6th, 36thor 83rd bond because it would increase the risk of the portfolio .... (?) Are things better for large portfolios ???...
On large portfolios the same messy pattern occurs on and on ... Notice that a n=320 portfolio has a smaller VaR than a n=400. Big n ... same pattern
...maybe there’s really some tricky risk in the 36th bond ! If we use a 3% VaR instead of a 5% VaR, the “dangerous bond” is not the 36th anymore, but the 28th.... (!?)
Coherency and convexity The lack of coherence of VaR and TCE is the reason why their risk surfaces are wrinkled displaying meaningless local minima. In such a situation, an optimization process always selects a wrong local solution, irrespectively of the starting point. In real life finance, on large and complex portfolios, such local minima for VaR surfaces are the rule rather than the exception. In other words, the local minima are not due to the simplicity of our chosen portfolio. They always surround a diversified global optimal solution. Even though manifest VaR subadditivity violations are very rare to happen when adding large (quasi-gaussian) portfolios, it is nevertheless true that on the same large portfolios marginal VaR systematically fails to properly assess the change of risk associated to buying or selling a single asset.
Part 3: Minimization of Expected Shortfall
PROBLEM ! A SORTING operation on data makes the dependence NOT EXPLICITLY ANALYTIC. Serious problems for any common optimizator. Minimizing the Expected Shortfall Let a portfolio of M assets be a function of their “weights” wj=1....M and let X=X(wi ) be its Profit & Loss. We want to find optimal weights by minimizing its Expected Shortfall In the case of a N scenarios estimator we have Notice: also in the case of non parametric VaR a SORTING operation is needed in the estimator and the same problem appears
Notice: the SORTING operator on data has disappeared. The dependence on data is manifestly analytic. The Pflug-Uryasev-Rockafellar solution Pflug, Uryasev & Rockafellar (2000, 2001) introduce a function which is analytic,convex and piecewise linear in all its arguments. It depends on X(w) but also on an auxiliary variable In the discrete case with N scenarios it becomes
Properties of : the Pflug-Uryasev-Rockafellar theorem Minimizing in its arguments (w,) amounts to minimizing ES in (w) only Moreover the parameter in the extremum takes the value of VaR(X(w)). (w) and ES(w) coincide but just in the minimum ! The auxiliary parameter in the minimum becomes the VaR
Properties of - linearizability of the optimization problem A convex, piecewise linear function is the easiest kind of function to minimize for any optimizator. Its optimization problem can also be reformulated as a linear progamming problem It is a multidimensional faceted surface ... some kind of multidimensional diamond with a unique global minimum
X1:N X2:N X3:N ....... XN:N ....... XN:N The role of the auxiliary variable The auxiliary variable is introduced to SPLITthe “5%” worst scenariosfrom the remaining “95%”. It is thanks to this variable that the data SORTING disappears. In the minimization process places on the specified quantile and gets the value of VaR.
Part 4: Minimization of Spectral Measures of Risk
Minimizing a general Spectral Measure M The “SORTING” problem appears in the minimization of any Spectral Measure
Generalization of the solution of Pflug-Uryasev-Rockafellar Acerbi, Simonetti (2002) generalize the function of P-U-R to any spectral measure. Also in this case it is analytic,convex and piecewise linear in all arguments. In general it depends however on Nauxiliary variables i In the discrete case it becomes
Properties of the generalized Minimizing in all parameters (w,) amounts to minimizing M in (w) Moreover, in the extremal, ktakes the value of VaR(X(w)) associated to the quantile k/N.
k 1 2 3 N X1:N X2:N X3:N ....... Xk:N ....... XN:N The role of The N auxiliary variables are needed to separate completely from one another all the ordered scenarios Xi:N In the case of a general spectral measures in fact, splitting the data sample into TWO SUBSET is not enough (as in the case of ES) In the minimization any kgoes to the quantile k/N.The vector separates all scenarios X.
Part 5: Risks and Rewards: are they really two orthogonal axis ?
An elementary observation ... A generic Spectral Measure weights all scenarios of a portfolio from the worst to the best with decreasing weights (decreasing risk aversion function). It therefore weights at the same time RISKSandREWARDS in an integrated way. .... -5.72% -4.94% -3.21% +1.23% +2.34% +3.03% +4.92% .... .... Φ(n) Φ(n+1) Φ(n+2)Φ(n+3) Φ(n+4) Φ(n+5) Φ(n+6) .... - Σneg.Φ(i) X(i) - Σpos. Φ(i) X(i) = + Minimizing a Spectral Measure amounts to a certain MINIMIZATION of RISKS captured by the negative contribute and a certain MAXIMIZATION of REWARDS captured by the positive contribute.
The simplest example ... Take for instance the case of a Spectral Mesure obtained as convex combination of ES(X) and ES100%(X)= - average(X) • This is a particular family of Spectral Measures with parameter λ between 0 and 1: • for λ=1 it is ES with confidence level • for λ=0 it reduces to (- return) • Minimizing this spectral measure already amounts to minimizing Expected Shortfall at confidence level and maximizing the return at the same time.
Integrated Markowitz problem One shows in fact that (Acerbi, Simonetti, 2002): minimizing with no constraints, for any λ amounts to minimizing with constrains, for any specified return value
Expected return Where for some Risk Minimization and Return Maximization cannot be disentangled. Given an optimal portfolio there always exist a Spectral Measure for which that portfolio is a “minimal risk portfolio”. General result More generally one can show that any point in the efficient frontier in the “Markowitz plane” of abscissa M represents also the unconstrained minimal solution for another spectral measure M,. • constrained optimal prtf for M • unconstrained optimal prtf for M,
Conclusions • The minimization problem of a Spectral Measure of Risk is a convex problem, but dramatic computational problems are encountered if a straightforward approach is adopted. • An extension of the P.R.U. methodology however allows to exactly convert the minimization problem into the minimization of an analytic, piecewise linear and convex functional. • Complexity can be further reduced by an exact linearization of the problem. • Standard linear optimizators (say CPLEX) allow to face in an efficient way the optimization problem of any Spectral Measure, under any probability distribution function for large size portfolios. • Splitting an optimization problem in “Risk Minimization” and “Returns Maximization” is arbitrary. All “optimal portfolios” in Markowitz-like efficient frontiers are in fact absolute unconstrained minima of other Spectral Measures. The trade-off between risks and reward is already taken into account in the choice of the risk measure itself.
References P. Artzner, F. Delbaen, J.M. Eber and D. Heath, 1999, “Coherent Measures of Risk” R.T Rockafellar and S.Uryasev, 2000, “Optimization of Conditional Value-at-Risk” C. Acerbi, 2001, “Risk Aversion and Coherent Risk Measures: a Spectral Representation Theorem” C. Acerbi, P. Simonetti, 2002: Portfolio Optimization with Spectral Measures of Risk