250 likes | 269 Views
Explore the application of game theory and risk analysis in counterterrorism, focusing on defense strategies against smallpox bioterrorism threats. Learn how decision-making methodologies like statistical risk analysis and game theory can inform optimal defense choices.
E N D
Game Theory and Risk Analysis for Counterterrorism David Banks U.S. FDA
1. Context Terrorists can invest in a portfolio of attacks. The U.S. can invest in various kinds of defense. If the U.S. fails to invest wisely, then we lose important battles.
A Smallpox Exercise The U.S. government is concerned about the possibility of smallpox bioterrorism. Terrorists could make no smallpox attack, a small attack on a single city, or coordinated attacks on multiple cities (or do other things).
The U.S. has considered four defense strategies: • Stockpiling vaccine • Stockpiling and increasing biosurveillance • Stockpiling, surveilling, and inoculating first responders and/or key personnel • Inoculating all consenting people with healthy immune systems.
Deciding What To Do Currently, the U.S. government is: • Holding public meetings • Soliciting scientific advice • Seeking counterintelligence • Calculating political support • Balancing alternative threats • Ensuring availability of options
But the U.S. government is not using: • Statistical risk analysis • Game theory • Cost-benefit analysis • Portfolio theory These are methodologies that can and should inform decision-making to counter terrorist threats.
2. Normal-Form Games • Classical game theory uses a matrix of costs to determine optimal play. • Optimal play is usually defined as a minimax strategy, but sometimes one can minimize expected loss instead. • Both methods are unreliable guides to human behavior.
Minimax Strategy The U.S. should choose the defense with smallest row-wise max cost. The terrorist should choose the attack with largest column-wise min cost. If these are not equal then a randomized strategy is better.
Minimum Expected Loss Sometimes there is more information and different structure than classic game theory supposes. This occurs in serial games, where probabilities can be assigned to future actions. This extensive-form game theory generates decision trees.
Extensive-form game theory invites decision theory criteria based upon minimum expected loss. In our smallpox exercise, we shall implement this by assuming that the U.S. decisions are known to the terrorists, and that this affects their probabilities of using certain kinds of attacks.
Game Theory Critique • Game theory does not take account of resource limitations. • It assumes that both players have the same cost matrix. • It assumes both players act in synchrony (or in strict alternation). • It assumes all costs are measured without error.
3. Risk Analysis Statistical risk analysis makes probabilistic statements about specific kinds of threats. It also treats the costs associated with threats as random variables. The total random cost is developed by analysis of component costs.
Cost Example To illustrate a key idea, consider the problem of estimating the cost C11 in the game theory matrix. This is the cost associated with stockpiling vaccine when no smallpox attack occurs. Some components of the cost are fixed, others are random.
C11 = cost to test diluted Dryvax + cost to test Aventis vaccine + cost to make 209 x 106 doses + cost to produce VIG + logistic/storage/device costs.
Assume that an expert indicates that: Dryvax and Aventis testing have costs that are independent and uniformly distributed on [$2 million, $5 million]. New vaccine production is not random; the contract specifies $512 million. VIG production is normally distributed with mean $100 million, s.d. $20 million. Logistics costs are normally distributed with mean $940 million, s.d. $100 million.
Other Cij s The other costs in the matrix are also random variables, and their distributions can be estimated in similar Delphic ways. Note that different matrix costs are not independent; they often have components in common across rows and columns.
Other components include: Number of attacks; this is Poisson with mean 5, plus 2. Number of key personnel; this is uniform between 2 million and 12 million. Number of smallpox cases per attack; this is Gamma with mean 10 and s.d. 100.
Cost to treat one smallpox case; this is normal with mean $200,000 and s.d. $50,000. Cost to inoculate 25,000 people; this is normal with mean $60,000 and s.d. $10,000. Economic costs of a single attack; this is gamma with mean $5 billion and s.d. $10 billion.
4. Games + Risk Game theory and statistical risk analysis can be combined to give arguably useful guidance in threat management. We generate many random tables, according to the risk analysis, and find which defenses are best.
We run 100 game theory matrices and count how many times each defense is optimal in terms of • Minimaxity • Minimum Expected Loss We also calculate a score for each, since the second-best defense may have nearly the same cost as the best.
Minimum Expected Loss The table in the lower right shows the elicited probabilities of each kind of attack given that the corresponding defense has been adopted. These probabilities are used to weight the costs in calculating the expected loss.
Scores The scores beside the left-hand tables are found by • Summing the maximum costs in each row • Dividing each maximum by the sum • Allocating weight to the decisions proportionally.
5. Conclusions For our rough risk analysis, minimax favors universal inoculation, minimum expected loss favors stockpiling. This accords with the public and federal thinking on threat preparedness. And the approach can be generalized.