1 / 29

Resource Allocation in the Brain

T heoretical RE search in N euroeconomic D ecision-making (www.neuroeconomictheory.org). Resource Allocation in the Brain. Ricardo Alonso USC Marshall. Isabelle Brocas USC and CEPR. Juan D. Carrillo USC and CEPR. April 2011. Neuroeconomic Theory.

carlyn
Download Presentation

Resource Allocation in the Brain

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Theoretical REsearch in Neuroeconomic Decision-making(www.neuroeconomictheory.org) Resource Allocation in the Brain Ricardo AlonsoUSC Marshall Isabelle BrocasUSC and CEPR Juan D. CarrilloUSC and CEPR April 2011

  2. Neuroeconomic Theory Use evidence from neuroscience to revisit economic theories of decision-making • Examples of neuroscience evidence include: existence of multiple brain systems, interactions between systems, physiological constraints, etc. • Revisiting theories of decision-making includes: • Build models of bounded rationality based not on inspiration but on the physiological constraints of our brain  derive behavioral biases from brain limitations • Provide “micro-microfoundations” for elements of preferences usually taken as exogenous (discounting, risk-aversion, etc.) and processes taken for granted (learning, information processing, etc.) The brain is, so it should be modeled as, a multi-system organization

  3. This paper (1) Build a model of constrained optimal behavior in multi task decision-making based on evidence from neuroscience: • Different brain systems are responsible for different tasks. Neurons in a system respond exclusively to features of that particular task. • The brain allocates resources (oxygen, glucose) to systems. Resources are transformed into energy that make neurons fire (fMRI measure blood oxygenation, PET measure changes in blood flows, etc.). • More complex tasks necessitate more resources. Performance suffers if resources needs are not filled. • Resources are scarce: “biological mechanisms place an upper bound on the amount of cortical tissue that can be activated at any given time”.

  4. This paper (2) • Central Executive System (CES) coordinates the allocation of resources: • Active when two tasks are performed simultaneously. • Not active if only one task, if two sequential tasks, or if two tasks but subject instructed to focus on only one. • Asymmetric information in the brain: neuronal connectivity is very limited information carried by neurotransmitters reaches some systems but not others.

  5. The model • Three systems (0, 1, 2) perform three types of tasks: • System 0 (S0) controls motor skill functions. Needs θ0 are known • Systems 1 and 2 (S1 and S2) control higher order cognitive functions (mental rotation, auditory comprehension, face recognition)Needs θ1 and θ2 depend on task complexity and are privately known • Distributions F1(θ1) and F2(θ2) satisfy Increasing Hazard Rate (IHR) • Another system, Central Executive System (CES), allocates resources {x0, x1, x2} to S0, S1, S2 • Performance of system l is with l  {0,1,2}. • Systems are tuned to respond only to their task • CES maximizes (weighted) sum of performances of systems: U0+U1+U2 • Resources are scarce and bounded at k: x0 + x1 + x2 k • Each system requires a minimum of resources to operate: xl  0

  6. The model CEScentral executive system x0 x1 x2 S2 (spelling) S0 (lifting) S1 (rotation) Motor function 0“public” Cognitive functions 1 and 2 1and 2“private”

  7. Benchmark case: full information

  8. Benchmark case: full information Solution under full information (assuming (R) binds and (F) does not): Distribute k according to needs (θ0, θ1, θ2) weighed by importance (0, 1, 2) Utility of each system depends on total needs (sum of θl) but not on how needs are distributed among the systems (θ1v. θ2)

  9. Roadmap • Normative approach: optimal allocation given private information if CES could use any conceivable communication mechanism • General properties • Comparative statics • Positive approach: can this allocation be implemented using a physiological plausible mechanism? • Applications • Task inertia • Task separation

  10. Normative approach: optimal allocation given private information if CES could use any conceivable communication mechanism • General properties • Comparative statics • Positive approach: can this allocation be implemented using a physiological plausible mechanism? • Applications • Task inertia • Task separation

  11. The optimization problem Optimal allocation of resources when needs of systems 1 and 2 are unknown and CES can use any mechanism. Using the revelation principle:

  12. The solution • Optimal mechanism M: • resource capx1(θ2) for S1 • resource capx2(θ1) for S2 • Equilibrium allocation under M: • x1*(θ1,θ2) = min { θ1,x1(θ2) } • x2*(θ1,θ2) = min { θ2,x2(θ1) } • x0*(θ1,θ2) = k - x1(θ1,θ2) - x2(θ1,θ2) • What are the optimal capsx1(θ2) andx2(θ1) ?

  13. The solution Sketch of proof • Derive optimal allocation with only 2 systems (1 with private info.) • Use it to derive “priority mechanism”: • P1 : optimal mechanism under the requirement that S1 always obtains the resources it requests • P2 : optimal mechanism under the requirement that S2 always obtains the resources it requests. • Compare both priority mechanisms. Optimum is a hybrid of both: it behaves like P1 for certain (θ1,θ2) and like P2 for some other (θ1,θ2).

  14. Step 1: two systems • Consider first a resource allocation problem between systems S0 and S2 when resources are k’ : • Solution is to put a cap y2 (k’) on the resources awarded to S2 • Cap solves y • Under IHR, the optimal cap: • is continuous in resources k’ • satisfies resource monotonicity y2 (k’) k’ k

  15. Step 2a: P1-Mechanism • Consider now a “priority” P1-mechanism that awards S1 all its needs θ1. • Then, there are k’ = k - θ1resources left to split between S0 and S2 • From the previous step, we have: θ2 y θ’’2 y2 (k - θ1) [P1] y2 (k’) θ'2 k’ θ1 k θ'1 k

  16. Step 2b: P2-Mechanism • We can perform the same analysis with a “priority” P2-mechanism that awards S2 all its needs θ2 and divides the rest between S0 and S1 θ2 y k y1 (k - q2) [P2] y1(k’) k’ θ1 k

  17. Step 3: optimal resource allocation • Putting everything together • Si must be at least as well as under Pj: xi(qj)≥ yi (k - qj) • Si cannot be better than under Pi :xi(qj)qi •  If Sj is constrained, then Si can be as in Pi (and viceversa) θ2 y1 (k - q2) [P2] y2 (k - θ1) [P1] θ1 k

  18. Optimal Resource Allocation Optimal capsx1(θ2) andx2(θ1)are first strictly decreasing and then constant in the needs of the other system x1(θ2) = y1(k - θ2) if θ2< k2 k1 if θ2 k2 θ2 x2(θ1) = y2(k - θ1) if θ1< k1 k2 if θ1 k1 k2 (θ1+θ2=k) θ1 k1

  19. Optimal Resource Allocation Optimal capsx1(θ2) andx2(θ1)are first strictly decreasing and then constant in the needs of the other system θ2 k2 (θ1+θ2=k) θ1 k1

  20. Optimal Resource Allocation Equilibrium allocation (x1*(θ1,θ2), x2*(θ1,θ2))  unconstrained for “small” needs and fixed for “large” needs (with x0*(θ1,θ2) = k - x1*(θ1,θ2) - x2*(θ1,θ2) ) θ2 (k1,k2) (θ1,y2(k-θ1)) k2 (θ1,θ2) (y1(k-θ2),θ2) θ1 k1 k

  21. Properties • Equilibrium is unique (under Increasing Hazard Rate) • k1, k2 , k - k1 - k2 are guaranteed resources for S1, S2 , S0 • Resource monotonicity: if θ1, both x2 and x0 • Comparative statics. Same monotonicity principle: • If 2 (S2 more important), then x2* , x1*, x0* • If k  (more resource), then x0* x1* x2*  • Implication 1. Let 1 = 2. Fix θ1 + θ2withθ1 > θ2 • Full information: U1F = U2F • Private information: U1* < U2* • Better performance in easy tasks than in difficult tasks

  22. Normative approach: optimal allocation given private information if CES could use any conceivable communication mechanism • General properties • Comparative statics • Positive approach: can this allocation be implemented using a physiological plausible mechanism? • Applications • Task inertia • Task separation

  23. Implementation So far, abstract revelation mechanism: “announce θ’i, receive xi(θ’i,θ’j)” Can CES implement the optimal mechanism in a “simple” way and, most importantly, in a way compatible with the physiology of the brain? • CES sends oxygen to S1, S2 , S0at rates k1 / k, k2 / k, (k - k1 - k2) / k. • Systems deplete oxygen to produce energy. CES observes depletion which is a signal that more resources are needed (autoregulation). • If Sistops consumption, oxygen is redirected to Sj and S0 at a new rate. • If both Si and Sjstop consumption, the remaining oxygen is sent to S0. • Si grabs incoming resources up to satiation or up to constraint • Si doesn’t need to know needs or even existence of Sj • Si doesn’t need to know its own needs θi until they are hit • CES must be able to redirect resources and change the rates

  24. Implementation θ2 k2 If θ1 >k1 and θ2 > k2 If θ1 = θ’1 and θ2= θ’2 θ’2 θ’2 If θ1 > x1(θ’2) and θ2= θ’2 θ’1 x1(θ’2) θ1 k1

  25. Normative approach: optimal allocation given private information if CES could use any conceivable communication mechanism • General properties • Comparative statics • Positive approach: can this allocation be implemented using a physiological plausible mechanism? • Applications • Task inertia • Task separation

  26. Application 1: task inertia • CES has imperfect knowledge of the distribution of needs • CES gradually learns the distribution through observation of past needs • How should CES adjust current allocation rules based on past needs? • Learning: • Distributions Fi(qi|si) depends on unknown but fixed state si (is this task usually complex or simple?) • Prior belief of state is pi (si) • Realization of qit conditionally independent across periods • After Si reports qit in period t, CES updates belief over si • Assume Fi(qi|si) satisfies MLRP: needs are likely to be high (qi high) when task is usually complex (si high). • Lemma: Gi(qit+1|qit) satisfies MLRP: high qit implies that si is likely to be high which implies that qit+1 is also likely to be high

  27. Application 1: task inertia Assume si unknown and compare public info. (θ1t,θ2tknown by CES at t) with private info. (θ1t,θ2tunknown by CES at t) • Implication 2. Inertia and path-dependence of the allocation rule. • Under private info. and conditional on present needs, allocation of Si is higher if past needs were high: • If q2t-1 , then x2t(θ1t,θ2t) , x1t(θ1t,θ2t) , x0t(θ1t,θ2t)  •  consistent with neuroscience evidence on “task switching cost”.

  28. Application 2: task separation • Is it better to have an integrated system responsible for tasks 1 and 2 or two separate systems each responsible for one task? • Trade-off: • Integrated system allocates more efficiently its resources between tasks 1 and 2 • Separated systems require less “informational rents”: cap of S1can depend on announcement of S2 • Implication 3. • Integration of S1and S2 dominates when motor task is important (“low” 0) • Separation of S1and S2 dominates when cognitive tasks are important (“high” 0)

  29. Conclusions • The brain is a multi-system organization. • Bounded rationality model based not on inspiration but on physiological constraints of the brain  derive behaviors from brain limitations • Optimal resource allocation: each system has guaranteed resources (k0, k1, k2). More resources are available only if others are satiated • Physiologically plausible implementation. • Resource allocation under capacity constraint and asymmetric information provides an informational rationale for (not a model built to explain): • Better performance in easier tasks • Task inertia and task switching cost • Conditions for integration v. separation of functions • Model can be straightforwardly applied to standard organization problems: • Allocation of resources between research, marketing and production • Market split of colluding firms (no transfers!), etc.

More Related