1 / 41

Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: New methods for old limitations?

Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: New methods for old limitations?. R Scott Braithwaite, MD, MSc, FACP Yale University School of Medicine Connecticut VA Healthcare System. CEA Limitations. Difficulty interpreting “number” (ICER) Is $59,000/life-year good or bad?

cirila
Download Presentation

Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: New methods for old limitations?

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: New methods for old limitations? • R Scott Braithwaite, MD, MSc, FACP Yale University School of Medicine Connecticut VA Healthcare System

  2. CEA Limitations • Difficulty interpreting “number” (ICER) • Is $59,000/life-year good or bad? • A policy tool in search of a U.S. policy “lever” • Other countries use it (e.g. Canada, U.K., Australia, Netherlands) but U.S. payers don’t • Does not incorporate quality of evidence • An analysis based on a high-quality study may appear to have same certitude as analysis based on expert opinion

  3. New CEA Methods • Decision rules for interpreting results • Linking results to policy “levers” in U.S • Incorporating quality of evidence

  4. Question: How can we use CEA to inform statin formulary decisions ? • Case 1. 64 year-old female diabetic, prior MI, pre-treatment LDL 137 • Case 2. 41 year-old male, no cardiac risk factors or history of cardiovascular disease, pre-treatment LDL 167 • Note: Treatment of both patients endorsed by current NCEP guidelines

  5. Research to address limitations of cost-effectiveness analysis • Decision rules for interpreting results • Linking results to policy “levers” in U.S • Incorporating quality of evidence

  6. Introduction • CEA results estimate value • Value allows maximizing health given budget • What is high-value for one society at one time may be low-value for another society • So how to interpret CEA in the U.S. currently? • CEA results often presented together with simple acceptability thresholds (e.g. “$50,000 per QALY”) • Individual thresholds have little validity • Ranges (e.g. $50,000 per QALY to $100,000 per QALY) may be more valid and feasible

  7. Objective • To inform decision rules for CEA interpretation based on health care purchasing choices in US • Two distinct but complementary analyses to estimate upper- and lower-bounds of range

  8. Methods • Analysis #1: Estimate cost-effectiveness of “modern” health care • Individuals prefer cost/benefit of modern health care to cost/benefit of pre-modern care • If willing to pay for modern care, then should be willing to pay for services that have same or better cost-effectiveness as modern care • May inform lower bound for decision rule

  9. Methods • Analysis #2 :Estimate cost-effectiveness of unsubsidized health insurance • Individuals prefer cost/benefit of no insurance to cost/benefit of unsubsidized insurance • Free rider effect: Pay 1/10 costs, get 2/3 benefit • If not willing to pay for unsubsidized insurance, then should be not willing to pay for services that have same or worse cost-effectiveness • May inform higher bound for decision rule

  10. % Willing to Pay for Health Insurance No Employer Subsidy Employer Subsidy % Poverty Line <100% 100%-199% 200%-299% 300%-399% ≥400% Income (Family of 4) <$19K $19K-$37K $38K-$56K $57K-$75K >$75K

  11. Cost-effectiveness of modern health care • Incremental benefits of modern care • 53% of observed mortality decrease • 4.7 life-years • Incremental lifetime costs of modern care • $452,000 • Incremental cost-effectiveness of modern care • $96,000 per life-year • Approximately $100,000 per QALY Braithwaite RS et al, Med Care 2008; 46:349-356

  12. Cost-effectiveness of unsubsidized insurance • Incremental benefits of buying (for 1 year) • Mortality reduced by 18% • LE increased by 0.020 years • Incremental costs of buying (for 1 year) • $4100 • Incremental cost-effectiveness of buying unsubsidized insurance • $204,000 per life-year • Approximately $300,000 per QALY Braithwaite RS et al, Med Care 2008; 46:349-356

  13. Interpreting cost-effectiveness results • Cost-effectiveness of modern health care • Inform lower (less inclusive) bound for rule • ≈ $100,000/QALY • Cost-effectiveness of unsubsidized insurance • Inform higher (more inclusive) bound for rule • ≈ $300,000/QALY • $50,000/QALY unlikely to be valid • Acceptability range ($100,000/QALY to $300,000/QALY) likely more valid and feasible Braithwaite RS et al, Med Care 2008; 46:349-356

  14. Question: How can we use CEA to inform statin formulary decisions ? • Case 1. 64 year-old female diabetic, prior MI, pre-treatment LDL 137 • Incremental cost-effectiveness <$10,000/QALY • Favorable • Case 2. 41 year-old male, no cardiac risk factors or history of cardiovascular disease, pre-treatment LDL 167 • Incremental cost-effectiveness $420,000/QALY • Unfavorable

  15. Research to address limitations of cost-effectiveness analysis • Decision rules for interpreting results • Linking results to policy “levers” in U.S • Incorporating quality of evidence

  16. Background • Cost-sharing becoming a standard “volume knob” to control utilization in U.S. • Cost-sharing has • Great potential to control costs • Great potential to cause harm • Increasing calls to link cost-sharing to value (e.g. value-based insurance design) • No cost-sharing for high-value services • Same or increased cost-sharing for low-value services

  17. Background • Possible way to link cost-effectiveness results to cost-sharing • > $300K/QALY: Increase cost-sharing • $100K-300K/QALY: No Δ cost-sharing • < $100K/QALY: Waive cost-sharing • Cost-saving: Share cost-savings? • Braithwaite RS et al, Ann Intern Med. 2007; 146: 602-605

  18. Purpose • To estimate the impact of value-linked cost-sharing if it were applied systematically across US health system

  19. Methods • From RAND, we can estimate the impact of cost-sharing amount on health service demand • Results confirmed by >100 observational studies

  20. New year = new “pull” from cost-effectiveness distribution Age N Health expenditure Uninsured Insured Insured, value-based cost-sharing Value increases, lowers, or maintains health expenditures Prevailing cost-sharing maintains health expenditures High cost-sharing lowers health expenditures Mortality Age N+1

  21. Life Expectancy Gain (Years) No cost-shar, Expand insurance Value-based cost-shar Expand insurance Value-based cost-shar Current insurance Current cost-shar Expand insurance Current cost-shar Current insurance 20% 30% 40% 50% Copayment if low-value

  22. Annual per-capita cost (2003 $) No cost-shar, Expand insurance Current cost-shar Expand insurance Current cost-shar Current insurance Value-based cost-shar Expand insurance Value-based cost-shar Current insurance 20% 30% 40% 50% Copayment if low-value

  23. Conclusions • Value-linked cost-sharing may increase life expectancy from health care while reducing costs • Costs may be lowered sufficiently to offset incremental expenditures from expanding health insurance coverage

  24. Question: How can we use CEA to inform statin formulary decisions ? • Case 1. 64 year-old female diabetic, prior MI, pre-treatment LDL 137 • Incremental cost-effectiveness <$10,000/QALY • Favorable • No cost-sharing • Case 2. 41 year-old male, no cardiac risk factors or history of cardiovascular disease, pre-treatment LDL 167 • Incremental cost-effectiveness $420,000/QALY • Unfavorable • Higher cost-sharing (30%-35%)

  25. Research to address limitations of cost-effectiveness analysis • Decision rules for interpreting results • Linking results to policy “levers” in U.S • Incorporating quality of evidence

  26. Problem • Clinicians and policy-makers often wonder “what goes into the model” • Current methods for cost-effectiveness analysis take into account uncertainty from random variation but not from low-quality evidence

  27. Objective • Can we augment standard cost-effectiveness analysis methods to develop a sensitivity analysis based on quality of evidence?

  28. Methods • Basic concept of our approach • When potential information sources have insufficient quality of evidence, don’t use them • Instead, assume that little is known by using uninformative distributions over wide range • Don’t obscure questionable data under a “false veneer of mathematical certitude” • Warning! If you set evidence standards very high, not much of the available evidence may qualify.

  29. Methods • Assess quality of evidence using USPSTF guidelines • Study design • Design differs from controlled experiment • Internal validity • Results represent truth in study population • External validity • Results represent truth in target population • Our approach can be used with any evidence-evaluation hierarchy • We chose USPSTF guidelines because of ubiquity not because of rigor

  30. Methods • Set minimum standard in each evidence domain • These can be “dialed” up or down at will • Evaluate each possible source of evidence • If source meets evidence criterion, use its 95% confidence interval in the analysis • If evidence does not meet criterion, do not use it in the analysis • Instead use uninformative (“wide”) distribution

  31. Test Case: Directly observed therapy for HIV antiretrovirals • Base Case: No evidence criteria • All 17 data sources eligible for parameter estimation • Study Design set to highest standard (“1”) • 13 out of 17 sources were eligible • Internal Validity set to highest standard (“good”) • 9 out of 17 sources were eligible • External Validity set to highest standard (“high”) • 5 out of 17 sources were eligible • All three criteria set to highest standards • 3 out of 17 sources were eligible

  32. Results: All Evidence Braithwaite RS et al, Ann Intern Med 2007; 146:133-141

  33. Results: Internal Validity “Good” Braithwaite RS et al, Ann Intern Med 2007; 146:133-141

  34. Results: Study Design “1” Braithwaite RS et al, Ann Intern Med 2007; 146:133-141

  35. Results: External Validity “High” Braithwaite RS et al, Ann Intern Med 2007; 146:133-141

  36. Results: All 3 Criteria Braithwaite RS et al, Ann Intern Med 2007; 146:133-141

  37. Conclusions • Quality of evidence may have profound impact on the precision and estimates of CEAs • Stricter evidence criteria may produce more uncertain results because there are fewer studies to base assumptions on • Approach shows when evidence is not good enough for decision making • Need higher-quality information on HIV DOT

  38. Question: How can we use CEA to inform statin formulary decisions ? • Case 1. 64 year-old female diabetic, prior MI, pre-treatment LDL 137 • Incremental cost-effectiveness <$10,000/QALY • Value: Favorable • Likely <$100,000/QALY if strict evidence std? Yes • Decision: No cost-sharing

  39. Question: How can we use CEA to inform statin formulary decisions ? • Case 2. 41 year-old male, no cardiac risk factors or history of cardiovascular disease, pre-treatment LDL 167 • Incremental cost-effectiveness $420,000/QALY • Value: Unfavorable • Likely ≥$300,000/QALY if strict evidence std? Yes • Decision: Higher cost-sharing (30%-35%)

  40. Cost-Effectiveness Analysis Limitations (and possible solutions) • Difficulty interpreting end-result • Give policy makers decision rules demarcating low from intermediate from high cost-effectiveness • A policy tool in search of a U.S. policy “lever” • Link CEA results to level of cost-sharing • Does not incorporate quality of evidence • Let policymakers and payers specify minimum threshold of evidence for decision making

  41. Questions ?????? • Special thanks to • Mentors • Amy C Justice, MD, PhD • Mark S Roberts, MD, MPP • Funders • NIAAA • RWJ • Co-authors, including • David O. Meltzer, MD, PhD • Joseph King, MD • Alison B. Rosen, MD, ScD • John Concato, MD, MSc

More Related