1 / 29

On the bright side ...

The Planning White Paper: misconstrued problems, misinterpreted evidence, misconceived solutions Roger Levett Partner, Levett-Therivel roger@levett-therivel.fsnet.co.uk June 2007. The Planning White Paper (PWP) includes:

jerold
Download Presentation

On the bright side ...

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. The Planning White Paper: misconstrued problems, misinterpreted evidence, misconceived solutions Roger LevettPartner, Levett-Therivelroger@levett-therivel.fsnet.co.ukJune 2007

  2. The Planning White Paper (PWP) includes: Sensible procedural improvements (though many just undo problems created in 2004) Role for planning in carbon reduction, energy efficiency, renewables (though no concrete actions beyond those aready announced in Ruth Kelly’s Dec 2006 package) Excellent rhetoric on the value and importance of planning for sustainability. BUT ... Levett-Therivel On the bright side ...

  3. Rationale: decisions too slow, costly, uncertain: Creates blight, delays / prevents projects we need. Proposed solution: National policy statements define infrastructure needed Independent Infrastructure Commission applies policy to decide individual cases Model: Government sets inflation targets Monetary Policy Committee controls Bank of England interest rate to deliver the targets. Levett-Therivel Infrastructure

  4. Levett-Therivel Some evidence (from PWP)

  5. Levett-Therivel Speed: is there really a problem? ‘The [planning] process can take too long to deliver decisions, impose substantial costs’ Really big, complex cases are a tiny minority. Of Barker’s 6 picked examples, only 2 took over 43 months: Heathrow T5 and Dibden Bay. Ministerial decision often adds months. Often because of funding, wider policy consequences. This will still take time … unless the Commission has power to commit major public expenditure?

  6. Levett-Therivel Misleading case: Dibden Bay port • Barker presents as example of delay (over 3 1/2 years) and costs (£45M). But: • Environmental downsides well known before • Costs show how long and hard the developers fought despite knowing these • Time reflects planning’s fairness & transparency: weighing all evidence, not ‘bought’. • Developers should ask themselves whether it was responsible to try so hard - not criticise the planning process for scrutinising thoroughly.

  7. Levett-Therivel Blight? • ‘… generate large amounts of uncertainty. This can extend planning blight, severely affecting the lives of individuals directly affected by proposals.’ • MIPs usually ‘in the air’ for decades: • W Oxfordshire reservoir discussed since 70s • All London airports threatened since 60s • Central Rail on and off since 80s • Planning time only a fraction of total gestation, • often concurrent with funding (etc) negotiations. • It’s the threat of development that causes blight, not planning for it. If we want less blight, the answer is less new development.

  8. Infrastructure inevitably gets harder to fit: The best sites get used first: eg valleys where a small dam and a small area stores lots of water near consumers; flat direct transport corridors with least landscape and community damage. Each increment inevitably does more damage per unit of benefit. Land fills up (often around infrastructure) because of population and prosperity growth. Health, environmental, amenity standards rise. Levett-Therivel Diminishing returns

  9. Levett-Therivel Holding back the UK? ‘… can delay delivery of key infrastructure, with harmful knock on effects for communities, business, the economy and the environment. And it can, in some cases, deter promoters from bringing forward projects in the first place, threatening our ability to deliver the infrastructure we need to continue to thrive as a nation.’

  10. Levett-Therivel Infrastructure gives us ... • Road (inc motorway) ‘improvements’ to: • allow & stimulate traffic growth (inc long trips) • erode local cohesion and distinctiveness • deepen the disadvantage of not having a car • Airport expansion to: • increase net outflow of tourism spend • stimulate a totally unnecessary ‘air culture’ • grow energy intensive food imports • make negligible difference to business • Gas power stations to: • squander premium fuel at low efficiency • make us dependent on ex Soviet bandit states • encourage energy waste from low prices • dump social costs (eg mining communities)

  11. Levett-Therivel Climate change ‘National policy statements would need to address the vital issues of mitigation and adaptation to climate change. The potential impact of infrastructure on carbon dioxide emissions, and how to minimise this impact as far as possible, would have to be considered in developing national policy statements … National policy statements would also need to reflect the physical impacts of climate change on projects and the need for resilience throughout their lifespan …’

  12. IPCC, Stern etc, acknowledge: Risks of catastrophic climate change greatly increase above 2° temp rise / 450 ppm CO2 Averting this requires at least 80% cut by 2050 Politically easy options won’t achieve this: Eco-efficiency improvements are at best preventing further emissions increases Emissions Trading Scheme ineffectual (EAC) Carbon offsetting often a sham … or a scam Anyway trading only moves the problem around: someone, somewhere, has to actually cut CO2. Levett-Therivel Climate change: realities

  13. Levett-Therivel Implications for infrastructure • Serious emissions cuts necessitate much less • motor traffic • energy consumption • air travel (people and goods) • rubbish needing disposal. • Resilience requires much less reliance on long distance trade, resource flows, travel. • We’ll need less centralised infrastructure not more. • For National Policy Statements to genuinely ‘address’ climate change, they must presume against growth in centralised infrastructure.

  14. (1) Obviate infrastructure: Buildings comfortable with less energy Good local services that people don’t need to ‘choose’ to avoid: (2) Local, distributed, closed loops Microgeneration, district heat / cooling / power Market gardens, local food processing Waste digestion, pyrolysis, gasification, burn Rainwater, grey water, purification, recharge (3) Sustainable methods: renewable energy walking, cycling, light/heavy rail Levett-Therivel A really sustainable approach?

  15. Levett-Therivel The shape of things to come? ‘The 2003 Air Transport White Paper explained the need to expand our airports but to do so in a way that took account of environmental and other considerations.’ On Government/industry scenarios, aviation growth will cause 1/4 of UK total climate impacts by 2050. Independent scenarios: up to 4X total. BAA argue Stansted expansion inquiry should not discuss climate change because ATWP already ‘takes it into account’. National policy statement invoked to suppress examination of a huge policy contradiction.

  16. Levett-Therivel Misleading case: gas storage Barker: ‘the UK is moving towards increasing [gas] import dependence ... new infrastructure is needed to increase the UK’s capacity to import and store gas, with the market planning to deliver some £10 billion of projects by 2010.’ Implies it will be planning’s fault if stops ‘the market’ reacting quickly to keep us secure. Actually, gas insecurity was a widely predicted result of Thatcher privatisation. If 20 years later ‘the market’ is only now responding, we need more energy planning not less. And better to reduce demand than hustle for supply.

  17. Levett-Therivel An unsuitable model Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee pulls one policy lever to manage one numerical variable. All collateral effects left to other instruments. Barker sees infrastructure planning by analogy as a one-dimensional task of clearing developers to pour concrete fast enough to keep up with business demands. This ignores all the complexities and conflicts that make planning necessary.

  18. Levett-Therivel Conclusions on infrastructure The country’s economic well-being is not imperilled by an inability to make snap decisions to build ports, airports, railway lines, motorways, reservoirs, power stations and such like in places nobody had ever thought of doing so before. If current planning process really has ‘deterred’ some infrastructure, this is a benefit. Putting the word ‘sustainable’ in front of aviation expansion, energy supply, economic development (etc) does not magically make them so. White Paper’s climate change rhetoric bears no relation to its proposals.

  19. New process could be made less damaging if: Commission appointed by local government, environmental / social NGOs, academia - not ministerial patronage. Wellbeing as prime test of development. Growth or commercial profitability not assumed to be identical to or even consistent with wellbeing. Independent sustainability appraisal of national policy statements, with teeth. Options hierarchy: (1) avoid / obviate, (2) local close loop solution, (3) most sustainable mode / trechnology. Levett-Therivel Damage limitation

  20. Levett-Therivel Economic development ‘We will amend the statement of general principles to … recognise the benefits that development, if properly planned for, can bring, including those that can flow from economic development ... in determining planning applications, local planning authorities must pay full regard to the economic, as well as the environmental and social, benefits of sustainable new development.’ Barker asserts that planning system is biassed against economic development. Example: IKEA expansion thwarted by planning.

  21. Levett-Therivel Misleading case: IKEA • ‘With average 750 staff per store, would have increased employment and driven competition in the sector.’ But IKEA is competitive because • standardisation/automation allows low staffing • sourcing from low cost countries • So more IKEAs likely to mean: • net loss of UK retail and manufacturing jobs • existing retailers forced to copy or go bust • less in-town retailing, more out of town. • Job losses might be offset by sector growth. But: • no attempt to compare + with - • does more Weetabix furniture make us happier?

  22. Levett-Therivel Misleading case: IKEA ‘[IKEA expansion] also had potential to lower long-distance drive times: over 30% customers drove > 2 hours due to lack of local stores.’ Yes, some of them will probably drive less far. But more people will drive to the new IKEAs … And more still will have to when new IKEAs have killed their town centre competitors. Again Barker makes no attempt to compare + and - effects.

  23. Levett-Therivel Misleading case: IKEA ‘… despite some local authorities wanting to attract to their area.’ Doesn’t mean more IKEAs makes UK better - merely that if you’re going to get the disbenefits anyway, you may as well try to get benefits too. ‘IKEA has now changed its business model, making a major retailer cause less traffic and inequity is a success! but this may lead to higher construction and operating costs and lower capital returns …’ ie lower multinational profits, better communities, buildings, lower externalities. This too is success!

  24. Levett-Therivel Misleading case: waste projects Barker: ‘90% of waste applications are granted [but] there is some anecdotal evidence that a number of applications for waste disposal or recovery do not come forward at all.’ No end of applications are possible. If any ‘do not come forward’ because everyone sees they cannot meet requirements on (eg) noise, smell, traffic, access or proximity, planning both prevents undesirable development and saves everyone time. Principle applies to all kinds of development. Barker presents no evidence that any proposals deterred by planning would have been desirable.

  25. Levett-Therivel The ambiguity of refusals • Barker and PWP assume that refusal of planning permission means loss of economic benefit. • High refusal rate could mean: • plan unreasonably restrictive • plan unclear, ambiguous, poorly explained • planners make capricious/inconsistent decisions • Or that potential profits are so high that developers keep ‘trying it on’ (Eg London?)

  26. Levett-Therivel The ambiguity of refusals • Low refusal rate couldmean: • plan effectively encourages good development • good planner-developer partnership • development the plan seeks is also profitable • Or plan is too weak, planners overstretched, councillors too craven, to stop bad development.

  27. Levett-Therivel The ambiguity of refusals • Refused development may be a net loss to the community whose planners foolishly spurn it. • Or it may: • avoid blocking something more beneficial • go somewhere else more suitable • come back improved, and be accepted • be good riddance to bad rubbish. • Barker: • only acknowledges a few of these possibilities • makes no attempt to assess relative prevalence. • … so no meaningful conclusions can be drawn about whether refusal rates are good or bad news.

  28. Levett-Therivel Benefits or disbenefits? Barker: ‘The planning system will rightly have a negative impact on investment in some circumstances due to its need to consider economic, environmental and social objectives. Turning down applications that will have a net cost to society is an important function of the planning system. An application likely to damage the local environment, or impose a poor quality of design on a community, may often be correctly refused.’ Quite so. But ...

  29. Levett-Therivel Benefits or disbenefits? Barker quotes evidence only business downsides. Even this is either pre-2000 or uncorroborated, uncontextualised business anecdotes. No attempt to identify or assess the social or environmental benefits of planning, let alone compare these with the business costs. … a staggeringly unbalanced and flimsy basis for arguing that the planning system needs to be rebalanced in favour of development!

More Related