310 likes | 322 Views
This outline explores the criteria for evaluating a tax system and the factors to consider when choosing components of the tax base. It examines distributional effects, neutrality, fairness, transparency, administration and compliance, flexibility, stability, and ease of transition. Additionally, it discusses the main tax base options, such as earnings, savings income, and spending, and considers the implications of taxing saving. The text language is English.
E N D
The choice of tax base Stuart Adam
Outline • Criteria for evaluating a tax system • Choosing components of the tax base • The choice of principal tax base • Some specific areas
Criteria for evaluating a tax system • Distributional effects • Distortion of behaviour (neutrality) and effect on long-run growth • Horizontal equity (neutrality) and other conceptions of fairness, privacy etc • Transparency (simplicity) • Ease of administration and compliance (simplicity), level of evasion and avoidance • Flexibility • Stability and ease of transition
What could tax bills depend on? The main tax base: • Earnings, savings income, spending Also used: • Hours of work • Past earnings / taxes paid • Age, marital / partnership status, number and age of children, disability Almost never used: • Sex, race, height, birthweight, parents’ characteristics, education, IQ etc
What should tax bills depend on? The ‘optimal contracting’ perspective: • should use anycostlessly observable characteristic that provides additional information about earning ability, responsiveness to taxation or needs But… • Nothing is costlessly observable! • Must trade off precision against complexity • This takes no account of horizontal equity • On which characteristics is it legitimate to discriminate?
The principal tax base • Little argument that should be something like earnings, income or expenditure • The best feasible guide to ability to pay • Individual or family? Measured over what period? • But which? • This largely boils down to the question of how to tax saving
A baseline: zero tax on saving Two arguments for zero tax on saving: • Don’t discourage saving • Treat all capital the same • Simplest route to equal taxation is zero taxation
Don’t discourage saving Goes back to Atkinson & Stiglitz (1976)… • Saving just defers consumption • A tax on saving means taxing earnings spent tomorrow more than earnings spent today • Under certain conditions, this decision to delay consumption tells us nothing about ability to earn • So taxing saving is an inefficient way to redistribute • Tax those with high earnings/spending, not those who choose to spend their earnings later
On the other hand… Conditions for Atkinson-Stiglitz don’t hold: • If work decisions depend on the timing of consumption • If consumption substitutes for leisure then tax retirement saving to encourage work • If high-ability people have higher saving rates (eg more patient, longer life expectancy) • Then saving indicates high ability, not just consumption preferences • If we think about trying to tax earnings over time • Keep wealth low so you can tax earnings without people stopping work • With decisions taken under uncertainty (over various things) There are many other (complicated!) arguments • See Banks/Diamond/Mirrlees draft chapter
The upshot • Theoretical arguments for zero capital taxation don’t survive without unrealistic assumptions • But the basic intuition still seems sound • Arbitrarily high taxation of long-delayed consumption seems wrong • And the objections give little guidance on how much to tax saving • No reason to tax capital income at the same rate as earnings • Maybe focus more on practical considerations • How easy would it be to tax capital income ‘properly’? • How easy would it be to move to zero taxation of saving?
How might we not tax saving? • Present value of lifetime earnings and expenditure are the same if all saving earns the normal return r • Ignoring bequests: a tricky issue! So three mechanisms: • Just tax earnings: National Insurance contributions • Just tax expenditure: VAT • Tax expenditure, calculated as: earnings – net contributions into saving accounts • In all cases, no tax on the return that converts earning today into spending tomorrow
Earnings or expenditure? • Not all saving earns the normal return • Expenditure tax captures higher (or lower) returns • Equivalent to an earnings tax with the proceeds invested in the same way as the private savings • Does this matter? Depends why return varies… • Risky returns don’t change much • Scale up holding of risky assets • Not quite equivalent as tax isn’t proportional • ‘Rents’ do change things • Some exceptional returns due to market power, factors in fixed supply, entrepreneurship, etc • Often efficient to tax these • How much of these are at the corporate level?
Income tax treatment of saving Default is to tax returns to saving (interest, dividends, capital gains) as well as earnings • at lower rates: dividend tax credit, CGT allowance / taper But… • ISAs: returns tax-exempt (earnings tax treatment) • Housing & other durables: ditto • Pensions: expenditure tax treatment • contributions deducted from taxable income • returns within the fund untaxed • withdrawals (pension income) mostly taxed These account for most saving for most people
Other taxes on capital • Corporation tax • Stamp duties • Council tax • Business rates • Inheritance tax • Withdrawal of means-tested benefits
Treat all capital the same “the attraction of an expenditure tax is not so much that it would remove a disincentive to saving in general but that it offers a practicable way of eliminating the differential taxation of particular forms of saving and capital income” Kay & King (1990), p.96
There has been progress A general levelling of treatment since 1979 • Abolition of tax relief on mortgage interest and life assurance • had provided significant net subsidies • Introduction of personal pensions and ISAs • greatly extends access to tax-free saving • Alignment of income tax and CGT rates The decline of inflation has also helped
A comprehensive income tax? We would like to tax the accrued real return. But… • Hard to measure real returns in some cases • Taxing nominal returns means an ‘inflation tax’ • Hard to measure accrued capital gains • Taxing realized gains distorts towards delaying realization • Hard to identify an individual’s income within certain pooled savings vehicles • Problematic if we want a progressive tax schedule • Hard to measure the return to ‘investment’ in durable goods • notably housing • Hard to separate capital from income in some cases • eg annuities
A ‘pure’ zero-tax regime? • Pure earnings tax difficult for some things • Defined-benefit pensions • Pure expenditure tax difficult for some things • Housing and other durable goods • The current mixed selection has problems…
Tax smoothing • Pensions are taxed as deferred earnings • But the tax rate faced in retirement may be different • 40% tax in work, 22% tax in retirement • 59% tax + tax credit taper in work, 22% tax in retirement • 22% tax in work, 40% (or higher) benefit withdrawal in retirement • This can make pensions extremely attractive or unattractive • and favour strategic timing of pension contributions • Lifetime tax depends on the timing, as well as the level, of earning and spending • This seems both unfair and distortionary
If you can’t beat it, join it • Tax smoothing is inevitable as long as both earnings-tax and expenditure-tax vehicles exist • But if they were unlimited, everyone could smooth their tax base completely • This gives us a lifetime tax! • Almost: uncertainty is again a tricky issue
A choice of regimes (1) • This was exactly Meade’s suggestion • ‘Registered’ and ‘unregistered’ assets • Can choose to register new savings • Contributions deductible; withdrawals taxed • Otherwise, savings are simply ignored and only earnings are taxed • Certain assets must be registered (DB pensions, unincorporated businesses) • Certain assets cannot be registered (durables) • Otherwise, free choice
A choice of regimes (2) What would this require? • Abolish income tax on saving and CGT • Create new pension-type vehicles • No perks (25% lump sum, NICs on employer) • No limits, illiquidity or compulsory annuitisation • Create symmetric borrowing vehicles • Amount borrowed added to taxable income • Repayments deducted from taxable income
Other appealing options • Just make more use of VAT and NICs • Hall-Rabushka-style ‘flat’ tax • VAT with wages deductible; separate wage tax • No reason wage tax must be flat! • Nordic-style Dual Income Tax • A rational and feasible way to tax capital income?
Transition issues (1) • Windfall gains or losses for existing asset-holders • Created by all reforms, to varying degrees • Windfall tax efficient IF credibly one-off • Such (in)efficiencies may be large relative to the inefficiency of putting the wrong tax rate on capital • But gains/losses seem undeserved in any case • ‘Transitional protection’ could last decades!
Transition issues (2) • Changes in prices • Depends what reform implemented and how • No impact in the (very) long run • But short-run impact could be big: nominally denominated contracts, indexation of benefits, etc • Problems with all transitions • One-off administrative cost of change-over • Unforeseen teething problems • Professional expertise is in current system • Losers angry, winners ungrateful
Saving among low earners • Discussion so far has been about life-cycle saving • Save (and borrow) so you consume when it’s most valuable to you, not when you happen to earn it • This assumes rational, forward-looking behaviour • Actually seems to fit behaviour quite well over most of the distribution • But not at the bottom of the distribution • Evidence of myopia, self-control problems, framing effects, etc • Possible role for subsidizing saving for these people • But are irrational people likely to respond to incentives? • Can also have some strange implications • More favourable incentives might reduce saving
Pensions • Broadly expenditure tax treatment • But more generous • 25% tax-free lump sum • Employer contributions escape NICs at both ends • Why? Pensions need special inducement… • Must lock in the money until retirement • Compulsory annuitisation • May well be good reasons for this • But is the inducement well designed? • Why a percentage of the fund? • Why favour lump-sum withdrawal? • Why related to rate of employer NICs? • Highlights bizarre taxation of non-pension annuities
National Insurance • UK NI has become much more like income tax • Either make it a proper social insurance system • There is a good case for this • Or merge it with income tax • Reduced admin and compliance costs • Transparency • Significant transition issues
Stamp duties • A tax on transactions • 0.5% on securities, 0-4% on property • An insane tax • Reduces effective returns • Hinders the efficient allocation of capital • Cheap collection not enough to justify it • Only defence is that it already exists! • Windfall gains from abolishing it undesirable • ‘Slab’ structure looks particularly absurd • £1 higher price incurs £5,000 more tax
Conclusions • Theoretical arguments for tax-free saving not robust • Practical arguments still seem strong • Distortions have been significantly reduced • Still some clear improvements available • Maybe not quite as central as it was for Meade? • Focus more on other elements of the tax base • What characteristics is it legitimate to use? • How much complexity is justified?
The choice of tax base Stuart Adam