190 likes | 200 Views
Outsourcing versus integration at home and abroad. Stefano Federico (Bank of Italy). December 2008 Vienna. Motivation. Bernard, Jensen, Redding and Schott (2007, JEP):
E N D
Outsourcing versus integration at home and abroad Stefano Federico (Bank of Italy) December 2008 Vienna
Motivation • Bernard, Jensen, Redding and Schott (2007, JEP): “Further progress (…) will require explicit consideration of the boundaries of the firm, including the decisions about whether to insource or outsource stages of production, and whether such insourcing or outsourcing takes place within or across national boundaries” (p. 128, italics added)
Framework • Firms in need of inputs choose both location and organizational form
Related literature • Theory • Antràs (2003) • Antràs and Helpman (2004, 2008) • Grossman and Helpman (2004, 2005) • Empirics • U.S. trade data: Antràs (2003), Yeaple (2006), Nunn and Trefler (2008), Bernard et al. (2008) • Firm-level data: Tomiura (2007), Defever and Toubal (2007)
Our contribution (1) • For each firm, we observe % inputs acquired from: • domestic affiliates (DI) • domestic non-affiliates (DO) • foreign affiliates (FI) • foreign non-affiliates (FO) • Improvement on previous literature • Studies based on trade data do not observe domestic inputs
Our contribution (2) • Only “subcontracting” inputs are considered • Intermediate goods and services, in conformity with the acquiring company’s projects, technologies or prototypes • Fully consistent with theory (relationship-specific investments) • “To us, outsourcingmeans more than just the purchase of raw materials and standardized goods. It means finding a partner with which a firm can establish a bilateral relationship and having the partner undertake relationship-specific investments (…)” (Grossman and Helpman 2005, italics added)
Productivity ordering Source: adapted from Spencer (2005).
Headquarter intensity • Integration will be preferred to outsourcing when the contribution of final-good producer is larger • …i.e. in industries with high intensity in headquarter services (capital intensity, skill intensity, R&D intensity, advertising intensity, etc.)
Data and sample • Survey on Italian manufacturing firms (Mediocredito Capitalia), 7th ed. • Period: 1997 (1989-1997 for balance-sheet data) • Our sample: 3,819 firms (4% of universe) • Biased in favour of medium-large firms
Sourcing strategies Note: Sourcing strategies are not mutually exclusive % of firms (on sample)
Econometric analysis: 1 A given characteristic of firm i (VA, L, TFP, etc.) Set of controls: industry, area, export status Dummies for each sourcing strategy (relative to the baseline group DO)
Size and productivity premia All coefficients are significant at 10%. Coefficients for industry, area and export status dummies are not reported.
Econometric analysis: 2 Inputs from foreign affiliates on foreign inputs Inputs from domestic affiliates on domestic inputs TFP – fixed effects Indicator of headquarter intensity ( next slide)
Economic significance • Foreign integration • A one standard deviation increase in TFP results in a .21/.25 standard deviation increase in the share of foreign integration • A one standard deviation increase in capital intensity results in a .11/.12 standard deviation increase in the share of foreign integration • Domestic integration • Smaller values (.12/.14 for TFP, .07/.13 for capital intensity)
Robustness • Additional explanatory variables: • Firm’s wage costs • Firm age • Demand cyclicality • Demand seasonality • Area dummies • U.S. headquarter intensity measures (NBER) • Alternative methods: • Tobit • Probit • SURE
Conclusions • Productivity ordering: FI>DI>FO>DO • Consistent with ordering assumed by Antràs and Helpman (2004), except DI>FO in our case • To our knowledge, first estimation for all four organizational forms • Integration is more likely in capital-intensive industries • Controlling for both skill intensity and R&D intensity • Consistent with theory (Antràs 2003) and previous evidence