270 likes | 478 Views
Innovation, ennovation and firm-level productivity growth: a new Schumpeterian elaboration applicable in a development context . Dr Samuel Mwaura Hunter Centre for Entrepreneurship Samuel.mwaura@strath.ac.uk. Overview. Research problems/ paradoxes Gaps in innovation research
E N D
Innovation, ennovation and firm-level productivity growth: a new Schumpeterian elaboration applicable in a development context Dr Samuel Mwaura Hunter Centre for Entrepreneurship Samuel.mwaura@strath.ac.uk
Overview • Research problems/ paradoxes • Gaps in innovation research • Dimensions of knowledge capital • Innovation vs. Ennovation • Link to productivity growth
Research problem • Interest in the contribution of firms to economic development; especially the link between entrepreneurship and economic development, firm performance in LDCs • Early GEM studies ‘surprisingly’ found a U-Shaped relationship with very high levels of entrepreneurship in poor countries – no convincing explanation/ theory yet • Innovation conventionally recognised as the key driver of growth both the macro-level and at the firm and industry levels • Intuitive, but no convincing theory or empirical evidence, despite large surveys, e.g. Community Innovation Survey • The situation in developing countries inadequately understood. Little R&D, high imitation/adaption, but lots of ingenuity and new products in LDC contexts, especially by SMEs, yet low growth • What is the relationship between innovation and productivity growth?
Innovation Research: Schumpeter • Schumpeter: invention different from innovation • Invention is basic scientific discovery. • Innovation entails: new products, new methods of production, new sources of supply, the exploitation of new markets, new ways to organise business (e.g. Taylorization). • New combinations of factors of production in kind, i.e. qualitative changes in the production function, must produce changes in the output. Hence, development and not mere growth.
Innovation Research: Schumpeter • However… Innovation is ‘any doing things differently in the realm of economic life’; quite general and vague • Schumpeter Mark II – focus on R&D in large firms. • A clear shift from his Mark I emphasis on “carrying out” new combinations by entrepreneurs, to the “trying out” by large firms. • Based on observations rather than theory. Mark I in early 20th Century Europe (1911), Mark II in large corporations in America. • Ruttan (1959) - Schumpeter did not advance innovation theory at all.
Innovation Research: Knowledge capital • Innovation research prioritised ‘technological innovation proper’ (Archibugi, 1988) • So, R&D investments = knowledge capital • Assumed R&D always leads to new products • Fitted well within “capital accumulation” and the production function (productivity and growth accounting framework) • However… Thomas Edison is said to have tested 1,600 different filament materials before finding his carbon filament solution (Scherer, 1986).
Innovation Research: Knowledge capital • Is all this useful knowledge capital that contributes to actual production/ productivity? • ‘Swedish paradox’, high investments in R&D little growth (Audretsch and Keilbach, 2008; Ejermo and Kander, 2006) • Thus, R&D can be said to produce: • Purposed knowledge – the solution sought • Serendipitous knowledge – incidental discoveries • Mere chaff
Innovation Research: Knowledge capital • Besides R&D not producing useful knowledge, useful knowledge may not implemented • “Real options” to exploit in the future (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2002) • Hoarded knowledge not likely to be used • Nokia - 4,000 market ready intellectual properties but unused (Hossain, 2012) • Other problems with R&D and patents: • Non-use of the patents system (Carlsson and Fridh, 2002; Raustiala and Sprigman, 2006) • Duplication of efforts across firms (Dasgupta and Stiglitz, 1980; Loury, 1979; Temin, 1979). • “waiting games” (Dasgupta, 1988) and “inventing around” existing patents (Mansfield et al. 1981)
Innovation Research: knowledge capital • For small firms in particular… • Knowledge spill-over theory – new firms (spin-offs) exploiting knowledge developed by large R&D intensive firms (Acs et al., 2009) • For example, the semi-conductor and Bell Labs; Nokia-Finland Innovation Mill (Hossain, 2012) • Knowledge comes from different sources (Roper et al., 2008) • Open innovation (Chesbrough, 2003; Dahlander and Gann 2003)
Innovation Research • Back to the big question: What is innovation and how does it contribute to economic performance? • Oslo Manual 1997 – technological innovation proper – R&D, high-tech industries • Crepon, Duguet, and Mairesse (CDM), 1998: Knowledge capital exploited in production is observable as shares of new products in firm sales. • Therefore, knowledge production before production proper (CDM, 1998) • R&D = innovation inputs • New products sales = Knowledge capital= innovation outputs
Innovation Research • Oslo Manual 2005 – innovation happens everywhere – large firms, small firms, services, high-tech, low-tech, even governments • New focus: Innovation is about implementation – not just pursuit of novelty through R&D • However, innovation = implemented innovation • What is innovation again? • Back to CDM (1998) • Innovation inputs (R&D) → innovation outputs (knowledge capital, i.e. new products sales share) → productivity growth (through knowledge capital accumulation)
Innovation Research • However, very little of knowledge capital, proxied by new products sales shares, is accounted for by R&D (Mairesse and Mohnen, 2002) • Various sources of knowledge, e.g networks, not just R&D (Roper et al., 2008; Love and Roper, 1999), open innovation (Chesbrough, 2003; Dahlander and Gann 2003) • Therefore R&D + other sources = total knowledge capital • Implement this knowledge capital, you get innovation outputs (New products sales share).
Innovation Research • However, high sales share a poor proxy for knowledge capital as one piece of knowledge, one new product, can account for even 100% of sales • What then is knowledge capital and innovation outputs? • R&D = Innovation inputs • Knowledge from R&D = Innovation outputs • Conversion success (Extent of new products sold) = Innovation outputs’ outputs • Contribution to productivity = Innovation outputs’ outputs’ outputs • Serious equivocation issues
Innovation Research: knowledge capital • Besides, again, very little of new products sales shares is accounted for by R&D (Mairesse and Mohnen, 2002) • In fact, for the vast majority of small firms, the introduction of new products is something that ‘just happens’ (Vermeulen et al., 2005) • In developing countries, (small) firms churn out new products all the time with little R&D, whether imitations or basic ingenuity/ creativity.
Innovation Research: knowledge capital • In LDCs, unable to employ the conventional constructs of innovation such as R&D investments and “new to the market/ new to the world” originations, anything new at the firm level is considered as innovation (Mytelka, 2000; van Dijk and Sandee, 2002). • Methodologically, without R&D inputs, the structural CDM model cannot work in developing countries; new products do not derive from R&D. • Besides, since high new products sales shares may be from high sales of one new item, that may even be an imitation, sales shares a poor proxy of knowledge capital • Innovation research hamstrung by a “certain degree of ‘fuzziness’ with respect to basic concepts” (Fagerberg, 2004)
Rethinking knowledge: Three dimensions • Knowledge assemblage: the magnitude and substance of what is known. • A collection of “modules of knowledge”. • Each module of knowledge is produced, i.e. discovered, only once (fixed costs, but no marginal costs except for transmission). • Different modules have different levels of substance, e.g. General Purpose Technology has a higher substance than a solution to a minor bug • Knowledge lore-range: how many people are proficiently knowledgeable about a given module • Knowledge mileage: the extent to which a given module of knowledge is employed in actual production
Rethinking knowledge: Three dimensions • Since capital stock refers to capital employed in production, with intangible knowledge, it is the increasing the mileage of a particular module of knowledge, and not increasing the assemblage of knowledge, that is equivalent to increasing physical capital stock • Merely increasing the assemblage, through R&D, e.g. Nokia’s hoard, or increasing the lore-range through education, without employing the knowledge in production yields no output • Stocks of knowledge capital vs stacks of knowledge capital
Rethinking knowledge: Three dimensions • Developing countries - different scenarios: • High mileage, and therefore low marginal product, from old technologies • Low lore-range, and therefore low mileage, in new high substance knowledge (ICT, etc) • Low contributions to new knowledge, and therefore, no first-mover advantage/ technological leadership. Hence, low marginal product by the time they join the technological bandwagon • Low mileage in new low substance modules of knowledge (i.e. monopolistic competition). Highly prodigal introduction of new(ish) products, especially by SMEs
Innovation, ennovation and the pedigree of productivity growth • Knowledge is not innovation, since, as above knowledge can be treated as a factor of production (capital) • Back to the original Schumpeterian insight • Economic development (productivity growth) comes from “carrying out new combinations of factors of production” • From “novate” – simply make new • Thus, the essence is that change happens in/ to the firm’s production function. It is this that effects a change in the output, hence growth
Innovation, ennovation and the pedigree of productivity growth • Early research assumed change is only from R&D, so innovation = R&D • When this was not confirmed, investigate the indirect impact of R&D on productivity, therefore innovation inputs → outputs →outputs’ outputs • But we see, lots of changes ‘new combinations of factors of production’ with no R&D or any observable ‘knowledge’ inputs at all – the case with many small firmsin developing countries • We explain very little productivity growth • Alternative approach, try to explain ultimate output change itself proceeding backwards
Innovation, ennovation and the pedigree of productivity growth • Productivity/ production growth is wholly attributable to the aggregate of yet unidentified changes in the inputs side. Growth is the manifestation of these actual changes • Simulating Schumpeter, define, ennovation: the occurrenceof new combinations of factors of production • Simply captures the occurrence of change. Unlike innovation, no claim/ requirement that the firm/ entity in questions is the first to carry out this change. • Shares of sales of new products the extent to which the firm has shifted production towards new products
Innovation, ennovation and the pedigree of productivity growth
Implications • Separation of the various concepts and constructs • No need to consider sub-samples of innovators in research – selection bias issues • Inferencing extant studies, e.g. why R&D explains very little of new products sales shares. • Contributes to the growth accounting framework • Unriddles the “Swedish paradox” – high marginal assemblage of knowledge (through R&D), low mileage. Cf. Nokia • Operationalisationproblems remain, especially the mileage of knowledge