470 likes | 586 Views
Training Subsidies and the Wage Returns to Continuing Vocational Training: Evidence from Italian Regions. Giorgio Brunello (Padova) Simona Comi (Milano Bicocca) Daniela Sonedda (Piemonte Orientale). Training in this paper is. Formal
E N D
Training Subsidies and the Wage Returns to Continuing Vocational Training:Evidence from Italian Regions Giorgio Brunello (Padova) Simona Comi (Milano Bicocca) Daniela Sonedda (Piemonte Orientale)
Training in this paper is • Formal • Continuing vocational rather than initial vocational (after full time education has ended) • Mainly workplace training initiated by firms (but not exclusively)
Training matters • Broad consensus among policy makers that training matters for employment, productivity and individual well being • Yet applied economists do not have a consensus view on the wage returns to training
Two extreme cases • Lynch, 1992, finds that one week of training raises hourly wages by 0.2% • Bartel, 1995, finds that one day of training raises wages by 2 percent • The literature often finds returns of at least 3 percent for a week of private sector training – large relative to returns to 1 year of schooling (10 percent)
Estimating these returns is difficult Participation in training is not random Training correlated with individual un-observables (ability)
Methods used in the literature • Fixed effects estimates: • If un-observables are time invariant the within estimator is appropriate • required assumptions are: • 1. earnings growth is the same for participants and non-participants • 2. temporary shocks that affect wages do not affect training
IV estimates • We need an exclusion restriction • A variable which affects training but does not affect directly wages or the probability of receiving a positive wage • Difficult
The Acemoglu and Pischke model • Imperfect product and labour markets • General skills • Firms are willing to train even when the imparted skills are general • Frictions and imperfections reduce the transferability of skills
Sketch of the model • Two periods • First period: training takes place and the employer pays the training costs • At the start of second period the match may end because of an exogenous shock • If the match survives, bargaining over wages • Production occurs
Notation output Worker outside option wages Probability of employment
Wage setting • Nash bargaining • The firm has outside option equal to zero • Outcome of the bargain Training costs are bygones
The training decision s= training subsidy Training increases with the subsidy The subsidy affect training directly and wages and employment indirectly via training
Implication • Training policies such as training subsidies are a good candidate to instrument training in an earnings regression • However: national training policies that affect all individuals equally cannot work • We need that • training policies affect only some groups (ex: training policies only in some areas) • the intensity of policies differs among groups
In this paper • We use regional training policies (training grants) as instrument • They differ across regions AND over time
Italian institutional setup • Training policies are regional policies • Regional governments have substantial autonomy in • Allocation of training expenditures to their budget • Timing of their invitations to tender • Ability to pay quickly
CVT policies in Italy • Levy / grant type (funded by social security contributions with a grant mechanism to award funds) • European Social Fund (largest; Objective 4 during 1994-99; Directives 1 and 2 during 2000-06– lifelong learning) • Laws 236/94 and 53/00 • Industry based training funds (from late 2004) • Tax deductions (Tremonti 2001 and 2002) – time dummies
ESF, laws 236/93 and 53/00 • Funded at least in part by a compulsory levy of 0.30% on payroll • Regional implementation, especially from 2001 • Regional and time variation in expenditure plans and invitations to tender (impegni)
Our data • We collect from regional publications the regional invitations to tender associated to Laws 236 and 53 • Data on ESF expenditure plans and invitations to tender partly from ISFOL and partly from the National Audit Court (Corte dei Conti)
Resources allocated to training subsidies from the 0.30% compulsory levy Source: ISFOL, 2006
Empirical model T=training stock TS: stock of training incentives per head at constant prices
The specification • Contextual effects • Regional and time dummies (wage bargaining is national in Italy) • Changes in regional labour markets • Regional unemployment rate • Changes in R&D expenditure • Regional share of high tech industries • Reverse causality – negative shocks reduce wages and induce regions to spend more on incentives • First lag of training incentives
The data • Match regional data on training incentives with micro data (ILFI) • ILFI: indagine longitudinale sulle famiglie italiane • Collects current and retrospective information
Why ILFI? • Has info on wages and covers relevant period (1999, 2001, 2003, 2005) • Pluses: • Has good info on training – not only training incidence but also training episodes – plus retrospective info: can be used to compute training stock as discounted number of episodes • Minuses: • info on training duration has many missing values – we decide not to use it • Tends to omit shorter episodes (usually the case in household surveys)
Presentation of results • First stage estimates • 2SLS (LATE) • Variations on the main theme
Implications (ceteris paribus) • One additional real euro per head spent in training subsidies from time t-x to time t-1 increases the discounted training stock at time t by 0.6 percent, a small amount. • To increase the average individual training stock by 10%, regions would have to spend an additional 13.47 euro per head (40 million euro in Lombardia)
Comments • No evidence of weak instruments with cube root specification • 2SLS estimates: one additional training episode - that raises T by one unit -raises monthly earnings by 18.6 percent • A week of training raises earnings by 4.4 percent (average duration: 21 days) • LATE, not ATE or ATT
Marginal returns decline over time, especially in our baseline
Average marginal effect • Over a 20 years period, the average marginal effect of a training episode is 1.35% in the preferred specification
Exploring heterogeneous effects • Interact both the training stock and the instrument with gender, age and firm size • In the case of firm size there are significant differences
Interpretation of results: I • Small firms with less than 100 employees often don’t have the resources and the facilities to train • Small firms train much less than large firms • Marginal benefits of training are decreasing in the quantity of training • When policies induce smaller firms to train, the benefits are much larger
MCS MCL MB
Interpretation II • Small firms have lower bargaining power • In order to retain their trained employees, they need to pay higher wage premia
Potential biases I • Informal training • Additional subsidies raise formal training and reduce informal training: we over-estimate effects • Nothing we can do as informal training is not measured
Potential biases II • Additional incentives induce firms to choose longer training course and reduce shorter courses: we over-estimate effects • More incentives affect training quality as less productive courses are added in: we over-estimate effects • We regress average duration on training incentives and find no significant effect. If quality is related to duration this suggests that these biases may be small
Back of the envelope • If T increases by 1 today annual earnings of compliers increase by 2645 euro (from 14222) – this is not the average treatment effect • 1 euro spent in subsidies increases the training stock today by 0.002; hence earnings increase by 5.29 (2645*0.002) for compliers • After 10 years these increases are only 20 percent of current increases
Yet • Since the average effect on the treated is different from LATE, we cannot go further than this – we would need to know the wage return of a broader group in the population of interest
Conclusions • We find evidence that • The wage returns to training for those affected by training policies are relatively high • These large effects are mostly limited to small firms; trained workers in large firms who comply with the training policies have much lower returns
Conclusions • Training incentives work but moderately so: one euro per head spent in an average region (3 million euro) increases the stock of training by 0.6 percent