1 / 33

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax.

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be efficient. Chapter 16 Equilibrium Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p).

tsterrett
Download Presentation

Chapter 16 Equilibrium Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax.

An Image/Link below is provided (as is) to download presentation Download Policy: Content on the Website is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use and may not be sold / licensed / shared on other websites without getting consent from its author. Content is provided to you AS IS for your information and personal use only. Download presentation by click this link. While downloading, if for some reason you are not able to download a presentation, the publisher may have deleted the file from their server. During download, if you can't get a presentation, the file might be deleted by the publisher.

E N D

Presentation Transcript


  1. Chapter 16 Equilibrium • Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. • Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be efficient.

  2. Chapter 16 Equilibrium • Defer the discussion of the market supply curve to later chapters and only denote it by S(p). • At any given price p, how many units the suppliers are willing to supply.

  3. We have the market demand D(p) and the market supply S(p). • The market curve is the horizontal sum of the individual curves. • Put them together, we can determine the market equilibrium.

  4. Solve D(p*)=S(p*). • Three things at equilibrium • U max, profit max, market clears

  5. At p* (taking price as given), consumers choose the best they can afford (utility maximization) and this results the quantity demanded by all consumers D(p*).

  6. At p* (taking price as given), producers choose the best they can produce (profit maximization) and this results the quantity supplied by all suppliers S(p*).

  7. Furthermore, D(p*)=S(p*) implies that market clears. So we have an equilibrium.

  8. The idea is, at the equilibrium price, consumers max utilities, producers max profits, and the market clears. • The equilibrium price is determined by all, yet any individual is small so that when making a choice, he takes the price as given.

  9. When p< p*, typically D(p)>S(p), some suppliers realize that they can sell at a higher price to satisfy disappointed consumers. This results a price increase pressure. • When p> p*, typically D(p)<S(p), some suppliers are unable to sell and they try to undercut the current price. This results a price decrease pressure.

  10. The comparative statics is to see how the equilibrium changes when the demand or the supply changes.

  11. Look at an example: a quantity tax on a good. • A quantity tax is a tax levied per unit of quantity bought or sold.

  12. As it suggests, either suppliers or consumers are supposed to pay the tax t. • So whether the tax incidence, or who gets to pay and how much, will be the same in the two cases?

  13. Consider the case where the supplier has to pay. • Suppose at p, before the tax, suppliers supply x. • After the tax, if the suppliers supply x, the price must be p+t since what matters is the price that the suppliers can put into their pockets.

  14. Alternatively, suppose consumers have to pay the price. • Suppose at p, before the tax, consumers consume x. • After the tax, if consumers still consume x, the price must be p-t since what matters is the price that the consumers have to take out of their pockets.

  15. Are the two cases the same?

  16. Fig. 16.3

  17. Fig. 16.4

  18. We can also talk about the tax incidence a bit. • Imagine two extreme cases. One where the supply is perfectly elastic, the other where it is perfectly inelastic. • Suppose before the tax the equilibrium price is p.

  19. supply is perfectly elastic vs supply perfectly inelastic • In the former case, no way you can get producers to take in less than p. So consumers pay all the tax. In the latter case, no way you can make consumers pay more than p out of pockets, so producers pay all the tax.

  20. Fig. 16.5

  21. These two extreme cases suggest that the tax incidence has a lot to do with the elasticities of demand and supply. • When it is more like the former, consumers pay most of the tax. When it is more like the latter, producers pay most of the tax.

  22. Fig. 16.6

  23. Can also talk about the welfare loss of a tax. • A quantity tax t makes the marginal willingness to pay higher than the marginal willingness to supply by t. So for all units where MWP>MWS, there is a deadweight loss, i.e., quantities that should be produced, but are not produced.

  24. Fig. 16.7

  25. Alternatively, can calculates the change of consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus to reach the same conclusion.

  26. So why on earth is the market equilibrium so efficient (Pareto efficient)?

  27. Think about what Pareto efficiency means. • If MWPMWS, it is not efficient because say if MWP>MWS, at least a consumer and a producer can strike a price in-between to produce an additional unit and the consumer is better off while the producer is making more profit.

  28. It is clear that market equilibrium makes MWP=MWS.

  29. What about looking at consumers only? If MWP1>MWP2 (say 5>4), then consumer 1 can buy a unit of good in concern from consumer 2 at the price of 4.5. This will make both 1 and 2 better off. • Market equilibrium achieves MWP1=MWP2 because MWP1=p=MWP2.

  30. Look at producers only, if MWS1>MWS2 (say 5>4), then producer 2 can produce a unit of good in concern more and this increases 2’s cost by 4. Producer 1 can reduce its production by a unit and this decreases 1’s cost by 5. So in total, a cost of 1 dollar is saved and this saved cost (saved resource) can be used to produce. • Market achieves MWS1=MWS2 because MWS1=p=MWS2.

  31. Market achieves MWP=MWS because the market clearing condition. • Market achieves MWP1=MWP2 because MWP1=p=MWP2 (utility maximization). • Market achieves MWS1=MWS2 because MWS1=p=MWS2 (profit maximization).

  32. Chapter 16 Equilibrium • Key Concept: It does not matter which party pays the tax. • Moreover we have a first glimpse on why the market equilibrium may be efficient.

More Related