530 likes | 770 Views
2. Games and Strategic Behavior. Thus far, we have viewed economic decision makers as confronting an environment that is essentially passive. But there exist many cases in which relevant costs and benefits depend not only on the behavior of the decision makers themselves but also on the behavior of others..
E N D
1. 1 Zhigang LiUniversity of Hong Kong
2. 2 Games and Strategic Behavior Thus far, we have viewed economic decision makers as confronting an environment that is essentially passive.
But there exist many cases in which relevant costs and benefits depend not only on the behavior of the decision makers themselves but also on the behavior of others.
3. 3 Example 11.1. Should the prisoners confess?
4. 4 Example 11.1. Should the prisoners confess? Two prisoners, X and Y, are held in separate cells for a serious crime that they did, in fact, commit.
The prosecutor, however, has only enough hard evidence to convict them of a minor offense, for which the penalty is, say, a year in jail.
Each prisoner is told that if one confesses while the other remains silent, the confessor will go free while the other spends 20 years in prison.
If both confess, they will get an intermediate sentence, say five years.
5. 5 Example 11.1. Should the prisoners confess? It is often convenient to summarize the elements of a game in the form of a payoff matrix.
Three elements:
Players (2 prisoners)
Strategies (confess, remain silent)
Payoffs (jail sentences)
6. 6 Example 11.1. Should the prisoners confess?
7. 7 Example 11.1. Should the prisoners confess?
8. 8 Example 11.1. Should the prisoners confess? The difficulty is that when each behaves in a self-interested way, both do worse than if each had shown restraint.
Thus, when both confess, they get five years, instead of the one year they could have gotten by remaining silent.
And hence the name of this game, prisoner's dilemma.
9. 9 Example 11.2. Why did students have to wait in line overnight to buy Cornell hockey tickets?
10. 10 Example 11.2. Each year Cornell announced a time at which its ticket window would open for the sale of a limited number of hockey tickets for students.
11. 11 Example 11.2. Suppose that if everyone shows up one hour in advance, everyone has a 50-50 chance of getting a ticket, and that the odds of getting a ticket are the same if everyone shows up 24 hours in advance.
If you show up 24 hours in advance and everyone else shows up one hour in advance, you are sure to get a ticket.
But if you show up 1 hour in advance and others show up 24 hours in advance, you have no chance to get a ticket.
The same applies to other students.
12. 12 Example 11.2. Waiting only one hour has no cost to you. But you would be willing to pay $40 to avoid having to wait 24 hours.
A 50-50 chance of getting a ticket is worth $50 to you and a 100 percent chance of getting a ticket is worth $100.
Other students value these outcomes just as you do.
What will happen?
13. 13 Example 11.2. Your payoff if you and others arrive 24 hours early:
14. 14 Example 11.2.
15. 15 Example 11.3. Why do hockey players vote in secret ballots for helmet rules, even though they choose not to wear helmets when there is no rule?
16. 16 Example 11.3. Consider two hockey teams-- say, the Bruins and Rangers-- each of whose players can choose to wear helmets or not.
Not wearing a helmet increases the odds of winning, perhaps by making it slightly easier to see and hear, or perhaps by intimidating opposing players (on the view that it is not safe to challenge someone who is crazy enough to go without a helmet).
17. 17 Example 11.3.
18. 18 Example 11.3.
19. 19 Example 11.4. Why do people shout at cocktail parties?
20. 20 Example 11.4. Why do people shout at cocktail parties? Whenever large numbers of people gather for conversation in a closed space, the ambient noise level rises sharply.
After attending such gatherings, people often complain of sore throats and hoarse voices from having to speak so loudly to be heard.
21. 21 Example 11.4. Why do people shout at cocktail parties? If everyone instead spoke at a normal voice level at cocktail parties, they would avoid these symptoms.
And because the overall noise level would be lower, they would hear just as well as when they all shout at one another.
So why shout?
22. 22 Example 11.4. Why do people shout at cocktail parties?
23. 23 Nash Equilibrium
24. 24 Nash equilibrium in prisoners dilemmas
25. 25 Example 11.5. Should American spend more on advertising? Suppose that United Airlines and American are the only carriers that serve the Chicago-St. Louis market.
26. 26 Example 11.5. Should American spend more on advertising?
27. 27 Example 11.5. Should American spend more on advertising?
28. 28 Example 11.5. Should American spend more on advertising?
29. 29 Example 11.6. Should Michael accept Tom's offer? Tom and Michael are subjects in an experiment.
The experimenter begins by giving $100 to Tom, who must then propose how to divide the money between himself and Michael.
He can propose any division he chooses, provided the proposed amounts are integers and he offers Michael at least one dollar.
Suppose he proposes $X for himself and $(100-X) for Michael. Michael must then say whether he accepts the proposal.
If he does, they each get the amounts proposed.
But if Michael rejects the proposal, each player gets zero, and the $100 reverts to the experimenter.
It is common knowledge that Tom and Michael will play this game only once and that each has the goal of making as much money for himself as possible.
What should Tom propose?
30. 30 Example 11.6. Should Michael accept Tom's offer? Unlike earlier games, the timing of each players decision in this game is important.
The payoffs for this game are better represented in a game tree, rather than a payoff matrix.
31. 31 Example 11.6. Should Michael accept Tom's offer? Suppose Tom proposes $99 for himself, $1 for Michael.
32. 32 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch? The owner of a thriving local business wants to start up a satellite outlet in a distant city.
33. 33 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch? If the outlet is managed honestly, the owner can pay the manager $1000 per week and still earn an economic profit of $1000 per week from the outlet.
The managers best alternative employment pays $500 per week.
The owner's concern is that she will not be able to monitor the behavior of the outlet manager, and that this person would therefore be in a position to embezzle heavily from the business.
The owner knows that if the distant outlet is managed dishonestly, the manager can earn $1500 per week, while causing the owner a financial loss of $500 per week.
If the owner believes that all managers are selfish income-maximizers, will she open the new outlet?
34. 34 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch?
35. 35 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch?
36. 36 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch?
37. 37 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch?
38. 38 Example 11.7. Should the business owner open a distant branch?
39. 39 Resolving Prisoner's Dilemmas and Other Commitment Problems In games like the prisoner's dilemma, the hockey helmet game, the ultimatum bargaining game, and the satellite office game, players have trouble arriving at the outcomes they desire because they are unable to make credible commitments.
40. 40 Resolving Prisoner's Dilemmas and Other Commitment Problems For example, if both players in the prisoner's dilemma could somehow reach a binding agreement to remain silent, each would be assured of getting a shorter sentence.
41. 41 Resolving Prisoner's Dilemmas and Other Commitment Problems
42. 42 Example 11.8. Will the restaurateur pay the waiter extra to provide good service?
43. 43 Example 11.8. Will the restaurateur pay the waiter extra to provide good service?
44. 44 Changing material incentive as a solution to commitment problem The Mafia's code of silence, hockey helmet rules, tips for waiters -- all work by changing the material incentives facing the relevant decision makers.
But it is not always practical to change material incentives in precisely the desired ways.
45. 45 Example 11.9. Tipping What if the restaurant is located in a distant city the diner doesnt expect to visit again?
46. 46 Example 11.9. Tipping Unlike case of restaurant with local patrons, this waiter has no way to penalize the diner in the future if he leaves no tip.
47. 47 Moral Sentiments as Commitment Devices If commitment problems cannot be solved by altering the relevant material incentives, it may nonetheless be possible to solve them by altering people's psychological incentives.
For example, feelings of guilt when they cause harm to others, feelings of sympathy for the interests of their trading partners, feelings of outrage when they are treated unjustly, and so on.
These feelings may lessen the incentive to behave in opportunistic and mutually destructive ways.
48. 48 Two Standards of Rationality The Self-interest Standard:
A person is rational if she is efficient in pursuit of her own interests.
The self-interest model is often not descriptive.
49. 49 Two Standards of Rationality The Adaptive Rationality Standard:
A taste can be added to the self-interest model, but only upon a plausible showing that someone motivated by that taste would not be handicapped in the quest to acquire the resources needed for survival and reproduction..
50. 50 The Possibility of Honest Managers If the owner believes that the managerial candidate comes from a society whose members have been strongly conditioned to behave honestly, will she open the new office?
51. 51 The Possibility of Honest Managers Suppose that the effect of the conditioning is to cause the managerial candidate to be willing to pay $10,000 to avoid the guilt he would feel if he managed dishonestly.
52. 52 The Possibility of Honest Managers
53. 53 A taste A taste for actions that result in avoidable costs cannot be favored by natural selection unless others can infer the presence of that taste.
54. 54