470 likes | 592 Views
Life is Cheap: Using Mortality Bonds To Hedge Aggregate Mortality Risk. Leora Friedberg Anthony Webb University of Virginia Center for Retirement Research and NBER at Boston College Presentation for Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, PRC 22 November 2007.
E N D
Life is Cheap: Using Mortality Bonds To Hedge Aggregate Mortality Risk Leora Friedberg Anthony Webb University of Virginia Center for Retirement Research and NBER at Boston College Presentation for Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, PRC 22 November 2007
Aggregate Mortality Risk • Risk that annuitants on average live longer than expected • CANNOT be eliminated through diversification within annuity business • Difficult to hedge with life insurance business
Aggregate Mortality Risk • Affects annuity providers • Insurance companies • offering voluntary annuities • Employers • offering annuitized pensions • Taxpayers • through Social Security, PBGC
Aggregate Mortality Risk • Affects annuity providers • Insurance companies • offering voluntary annuities • Employers • offering annuitized pensions • Taxpayers • through Social Security, PBGC
Aggregate Mortality Risk • Affects potential annuitants • price, quantity in equilibrium • only 7.4% in AHEAD voluntarily annuitized • between 1993-2000
Aggregate Mortality Risk • Of potentially greater importance • Decline in generosity of Social Security and displacement of annuitized DB by unannuitized DC pensions may increase annuity demand • ? Increasing uncertainty about potential for dramatic medical breakthroughs
Outline • What is the magnitude of this risk? • How might this risk affect pricing of annuities? • What price should this risk command in financial markets?
Aggregate Mortality Risk • What is the magnitude of this risk? • Lack of agreement • Actuarial tables • yield point estimates only • e.g., Society of Actuaries • Social Security Administration • high, intermediate, low forecasts • but no confidence intervals • Lee and Carter (1992)
Aggregate Mortality Risk • What is the magnitude of this risk? • Lack of agreement • Actuarial tables • yield point estimates only • e.g., Society of Actuaries • Social Security Administration • high, intermediate, low forecasts • but no confidence intervals • Lee and Carter (1992)
Aggregate Mortality Risk • What is the magnitude of this risk? • Lee-Carter model • “leading statistical model of mortality in the demographic literature” (Deaton-Paxson 2004) • adopted by U.S. Census Bureau • performs well in sample • provides confidence intervals perhaps they are too narrow?
Aggregate Mortality Risk • How might this risk affect pricing of annuities? • Required reserves if Lee-Carter is correct to reduce probability of insolvency to 5% for 3%-real 50%-survivor annuity sold to couple aged 65-85, need reserves of 2.7-4.8% • Impact of using SOA projections if Lee-Carter is correct same annuity will be underpriced under SOA projections by 2.3-3.2%
Aggregate Mortality Risk • What price should this risk command in financial markets? • Historical covariances, 1959-99 • Impact of mortality shocks on longevity bond prices at ages 65+ • Covariance with S&P 500 (CAPM) • Covariance with consumption growth (CCAPM) • These covariances are very small
Aggregate Mortality Risk • What price should this risk command in financial markets? • Should be able to hedge risk at virtually no cost • How? Mortality-contingent bonds • two short-term bonds issued recently by Swiss Re • one long-term bond proposed by EIB, not issued • according to our calculations, this bond was overpriced, unless investors expected lower mortality than U.K. Actuary did
Aggregate Mortality Risk • What price should this risk command in financial markets? • Should be able to hedge risk at virtually no cost • How? Mortality-contingent bonds • two short-term bonds issued recently by Swiss Re • one long-term bond proposed by EIB, not issued • according to our calculations, this bond was overpriced, unless investors expected lower mortality than U.K. Actuary did
Outline • What is the magnitude of this risk? • How might this risk affect pricing of annuities? • What price should this risk command in financial markets?
1. Magnitude of aggregate mortality risk • Lee-Carter model ln (mx,t ) = ax + bxkt + ex,t kt = kt-1 – 0.365 + 5.24 flu + et , e = 0.655 • Details mis mortality by agex, yeart a, bare parameters that vary with agex fluis the 1918 flu epidemic
1. Magnitude of aggregate mortality risk • Lee-Carter model ln (mx,t ) = ax + bxkt + ex,t kt = kt-1 – 0.365 + 5.24 flu + et , e = 0.655 • Details mis mortality by agex, yeart a, bare parameters that vary with agex fluis the 1918 flu epidemic
1. Magnitude of aggregate mortality risk • Lee-Carter model ln (mx,t ) = ax + bxkt + ex,t kt = kt-1 – 0.365 + 5.24 flu + et , e = 0.655 • Implications for mortality trends LC estimated that a random walk with drift fits path ofk implies roughly linear decline ink decreasing rate of increase in life expectancy no mean reversion in mortality trends current shock tomyields almost equal % change in subsequentE[m]
1. Magnitude of aggregate mortality risk • Lee-Carter model ln (mx,t ) = ax + bxkt + ex,t kt = kt-1 – 0.365 + 5.24 flu + et , e = 0.655 • Implications within sample explains > 90% of within-age variances in mortality rates one standard-deviation shock tok 2-month change in age-65 life expectancy
1. Magnitude of aggregate mortality risk • Comparisons of Lee-Carter with other forecasts • more optimistic than SSA • close to SOA at ages 45-79, then more optimistic • Figures 1-3 • comparison of mortality forecasts, 2006-54 • comparison to recent mortality data, 1989-02
1. Magnitude of aggregate mortality risk • Comparisons of Lee-Carter with other forecasts • more optimistic than SSA • close to SOA at ages 45-79, then more optimistic • Figures 1-3 • comparison of mortality forecasts, 2006-54 • comparison to recent mortality data, 1989-02
Future life expectancy at age 60, various mortality forecasts Lee-Carter 95% SSA high Life expectancy, in years
Recent actual vs. forecasted mortality declines Males, 1895-1924 birth cohorts Ages 90-94 Mortality relative to 1989 Actual mortality, ages 65-69
Recent actual vs. forecasted mortality declines Females, 1895-1924 birth cohorts Ages 90-94 Mortality relative to 1989 Actual mortality, ages 65-69
Outline • What is the magnitude of this risk? • How might this risk affect pricing of annuities? • What price should this risk command in financial markets?
2. Implications for pricing of annuities • Two sets of calculations • Required mark-up/reserves if Lee-Carter is correct • impact of variance of expected mortality • Impact of using SOA projections if Lee-Carter is correct • impact of differences in expected mortality
2. Implications for pricing of annuities • Required mark-up/reserves if LC is correct • 10,000 Monte Carlo simulations • each simulation: draw baseline k, then errors to fill in mx,t • construct resulting life tables • compute premium required to break even, on average • compute annuity payments in each simulation • compare to premium • what % mark-up over premium will reduce probability of loss to x%? • or what % of EPV must be held as capital reserve • x = 0.05 or x = 0.01
2. Implications for pricing of annuities • Required mark-up/reserves if LC is correct • required mark-up is 2.7% to 4.8% • competing effects of age • uncertainty about mortality at older ages with time horizon • but, payments at older ages are heavily discounted • impact if eliminate cancer, all circulatory disease, diabetes? • increase PV of an annuity by 50%
2. Implications for pricing of annuities • Impact of SOA projections if LC is correct • no actual pricing data • and it would be difficult to use prices to back out mortality assumptions • without knowing assumptions about expenses, asset returns, annuitant characteristics • instead, we focus on recent SOA projections
2. Implications for pricing of annuities • Impact of SOA projections if LC is correct • compute EPV of payments for $1/year annuity • EPV if SOA projection scale is correct • EPV is Lee-Carter is correct • Lee-Carter value is always higher
Percentage Underpricing Resulting From Use of Projection Scale AA
Outline • What is the magnitude of this risk? • How might this risk affect pricing of annuities? • What price should this risk command in financial markets?
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Mortality-contingent bonds • can be used to pass mortality risk to those who want it • very recent examples
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Mortality-contingent bonds • Swiss Re • three-year bond, first issued in 2003 • if five-country average mortality > 130% of 2002 level principal will be reduced • if it > 150% principal will be exhausted
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Mortality-contingent bonds • EIB • 25-year bond, proposed in 2004 • mortality-contingent payments proportionally as annual survival rate for U.K. cohort aged 65 in 2003 • but EIB bond was not issued as planned • expected yield implied 20-basis point discount (assuming Government Actuary Department’s mortality forecasts are unbiased)
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • We price the EIB bond • had such bonds been available in U.S. • measure mortality shocks • as identified from Lee-Carter model • Berkeley Human Mortality database, 1959-99 • Social Security Administration data, 19xx-yy • correlation with S&P 500 • compute beta, risk premium from CAPM • correlation with per capita consumption growth • compute risk premium from CCAPM
The Capital Asset Pricing Model: (1): Where Ri is the return on asset i and Rm is the market return (2): Where Rf is the risk-free return
The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Rearranging (2): The expected return on asset i depends on the risk-free return, and the covariance of the asset’s return with the market return Important implication – idiosyncratic risk – the risk of good or bad returns that are uncorrelated with the market return do not command a risk premium Why? – Because an investor can diversify away that risk by investing a small amount in a lot of assets with uncorrelated returns – think of the “law or large numbers”
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Results • such bonds would not have been very risky • standard deviation of return is 0.64% • versus 17% for stocks
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Results for CAPM • correlation with S&P 500 • varies with age of bond’s reference population • for age-65 mortality bond, beta = 0.005 • 95% confidence interval of [-0.005, 0.015] • virtually no correlation with stock market • bond would command risk premium of 2.5 bp • for equity premium of 500 bp
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Results for CCAPM • hypothesis: mortality bonds pay out most when? • when mortality is unexpectedly low • and then resources that are roughly unchanged in quantity have to support more people • expect negative correlation with C growth
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Results for CCAPM • correlation for age-65 bond is -0.1958 • significantly different from 0 for all reference ages • mortality bonds should attract risk discount • in contrast with stocks • correlation is about 0.5 • should attract risk premium
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • Results for CCAPM • but mortality bond returns, C growth are very smooth series • covariance is extremely small, -0.0013 • resulting risk discount is 2 basis points • for risk aversion coefficient of 10 • contrast with EIB prospectus • proposed risk discount of 20 basis points
3. Pricing of aggregate mortality risk • What explains EIB bond? • apparently overpriced • EIB expected to pass risk further by obtaining reinsurance • Smetters, Dowd: insurance markets are small, constrained compared to financial markets, which can bear large risks better • maybe investors expected better mortality • compared to U.K. Actuary’s forecasts • and might have perceived risk discount as less than 20 BP
Conclusions • Aggregate mortality risk is considerable • But uncorrelated with other financial risks • annuity providers should be able to shed aggregate mortality risk at virtually no cost • Of growing importance • demand for voluntary annuitization might be expected to rise