540 likes | 558 Views
CH 2 Health and Health Behavior. Outline. An economic model of utility, health, and medical care Measuring health status Empirical evidence on health production Health care expenditures. A Basic Economic Model. Health as a consumer durable good: Utility = U (X, H ealth)
E N D
Outline • An economic model of utility, health, and medical care • Measuring health status • Empirical evidence on health production • Health care expenditures
A Basic Economic Model • Health as a consumer durable good: • Utility = U (X, Health) • X represents “other goods and services” • H is a stock -- every action will affect health • On its own or combined with other goods and services, the stock of H generates a flow of services that yield satisfaction=utility
A Basic Economic Model (cont.) • Medical care is not homogeneous and differs in: • Structural quality (e.g. facilities and labor) • Process quality (e.g. waiting time, case mgmt.) • Outcome quality (e.g. patient satisfaction, mortality) • Therefore medical services are often difficult to quantify
A Basic Economic Model (cont.) Health=H(Profile, Medical Care, Lifestyle, Socioeconomic Status, Environment) • If an individual has a heart attack, then overall health decreases, regardless of the amount of medical care consumed • The total product curve for medical care shifts down • As a person ages, both health and the marginal product of medical care are likely to fall • The total product curve shifts down and flattens out
MEASURING HEALTH • Important for all health care managers today • Insurers and consumers are demanding costs AND quality
HEALTH OVER THE LIFE CYCLE HEALTH Appendicitis Auto Crash Cancer (radiation therapy) Cancer complications Hmin TIME BIRTH
Older people have a higher deprecation rate. That is why they have a higher health expenditure
HEALTH OVER THE LIFE CYCLE • Individuals make choices about health (make tradeoffs) which maximize U over time • Relatively high value for the future • Low discount rate • e.g. Low-fat diet and exercise to avoid heart disease • Relatively low value for the future • High discount rate • e.g. Smoking, excess drinking, drug abuse
DISCOUNTING • Required when costs are incurred in the future • Why? Individuals have a positive value of time preference • If r = 10%, then $100 invested today yields $110 next year • Spending $100 one year from now is “cheaper” than spending $100 today
DISCOUNTING CHOICES Invest $100 = $90.91 (1 + .10) and have $9.09 left over Spend $100 today
DISCOUNTING • If costs occur over multiple time periods, we must calculate the present discounted value (PDV) of these costs: T Σ 1 (1 + r)t PDV = COSTSt t = 0 • Example: A project requires: $100 in year 1 $ 75 in year 2 $ 50 in year 3 75 (1 + .10) 50 (1 + .10)2 PDV = $100 + $ + $ = $209.50
DISCOUNTING • If we discount costs, we must also discount benefits Assume r = 10% $990 Invest $900 to save 1 year of life next year and have $90 left to spend this year Spend $990 to save 1 year of life today
DISCOUNTING • Appropriate discount rate? • The medical literature has settled on 5% for comparative reasons • Discounting is not an adjustment for inflation 1 (1 + r)t COST Σ COST YOLS = 1 (1 + r)t Σ YOLS
Why we discount cost AND benefits • Consider an intervention which costs $100 and saves 10 years of life • Also assume r = 10% Option 1: Spend $100 today: = = 10 C E 100 10 Option 2: Invest for 1 year → $110, saves 11 YOL. If we discount costs to present value, but don’t discount YOL: C E 100 11 1 11 = = 9 • If we discount both costs and benefits: 1 (1 + .10) 110 C E = = 10 1 (1 + .10) 11
Measure of health capital • Mortality • Morbidity • Quality of life
MORTALITY • Alive vs. Dead • Advantages: • Disadvantages:
MORTALITY MEASURES 19501970198019902000 1. Crude death rate 963.8 945.3 878.3 863.8 873.6 (per 100,000) 2. Age-adjusted death rate 1446.0 1222.6 1039.1 938.7 869.0 3. Age-specific death rate 15-24 128.1 127.7 115.4 99.2 81.5 65-74 4067.7 3582.7 2994.9 2648.6 2432.9 4. Infant mortality 29.2 20.0 12.6 9.2 6.9 Neo-natal 20.5 15.1 8.5 5.8 4.6 Postneonatal 8.7 4.9 4.1 3.4 2.3 5. Life Expectancy 68.2 70.8 73.7 75.4 76.9 (at birth)
MORTALITY MEASURES • Life expectancy NOT a prediction of how long people live • 76.9 is a summary of age-specific death rates in 2000 • “If those born in 2000 experienced age-specific death rates prevailing in 2000, on average they would live to be 76.9
MORBIDITY • The relative incidence of disease • Advantages: • Captures quality of life • Disadvantages: • Difficult to measure • Difficult to aggregate when patient has >1 problem
MORBIDITY • Acute disease • e.g. appendicitis, pneumonia, gun shot wounds • Chronic disease • e.g. arthritis, diabetes, asthma • Incidence • occurrence of new cases in any particular year • Prevalence • new and ongoing cases in any particular year • Heart disease is more prevalent, but its incidence is declining
MEASURING MORBIDITY • Distinguish between symptom and disease • e.g. high blood pressure vs. stroke • Disabilities are also a sign of morbidity • Subjective measures - i.e. self-rated health • “Is your health excellent/good/fair/poor?” • Problem: 1970-80, # of people with high blood pressure declined. But % of people reporting restricted activity due to HTN doubled! • Depends on what you want to do - e.g. astronaut, airline pilot, or professor?
MEASURING MORBIDITY • How far do we go in classifying “medical” problems? • e.g. cosmetic surgery • Beware of phrases in contracts or policy statements such as “providing all medical care” or “basic needs”
QALY: quality adjusted life year • Perfect health = 1; death = 0 • Assigning utilities to some health state: what is the QALY for someone without the • ability to walk? Say, 0.4. • This QALY forms the basis for a cost-effectiveness evaluation of the treatment
QALY and cost effective • Example: a treatment confers two years of living, max. • Year 1: 0.9 of survival; QALY is 0.8 • Year 2: 0.5 of survival; QALY is 0.6 • Discount rate is 0.05 or 5% • Total QALY is 0.9*0.8/1.05 + 0.5*0.6/(1.05)2 = 0.96 • So the treatment confers 0.96 QALY
LEADING CAUSES AND NUMBER OF DEATHS, PERSONS AGED 15-24 (2000) CAUSE OF DEATH DEATHS Unintential injuries 14,113 Homicide 4,939 Suicide 3,994 TOTAL “Violent Deaths” 23,046 85% Cancer 1,713 Heart Disease 1,031 Congenital anomalies 441 All other nonviolent causes 757 TOTAL “Nonviolent Deaths” 3,942 15%
LEADING CAUSES AND NUMBER OF DEATHS, PERSONS AGED 65+ (2000) CAUSE OF DEATH DEATHS Heart disease 593,707 Cancer 392,366 Cerebrovascular Disease 148,045 (Stroke) Chronic Lower Respiratory Disease 106,375 Pneumonia and Influenza 58,557 Diabetes mellitus 52,414 Alzheimer’s disease 48,993 Kidney disease 31,225 Unintentional Injuries 31,050
Empirical Evidence on Health Prod’n • Hadley (1982) a 10% ↑ in medical care $ per capita →↓mortality rate by only 1.5% • Auster et al. (1969) 10% ↑ in medical services →↓age-adjusted mortality rate by 1% • Enthoven (1980) “flat-of-the-curve” medicine
LIFESTYLE • cigarette smoking 10% → mortality: blackswhites men 45-64 2.3% 1.4% women 45-64 1.1% 1.1% (Hadley, 1982) • A one-pack-a-day smoker incurs 10.9 more sick days every six months than a comparable non-smoker (Leigh and Fries, 1992) • Not smoking, regular exercise, moderate/no use of alcohol, 7-8 hours of sleep per day, proper weight, eating breakfast, and no snacking leads to 28% lower mortality for men, 43% lower for women (Breslow and Enstrom, 1980)
OTHER FACTORS AFFECTING HEALTH • Education • One more year of schooling →↓prob of dying w/in 10 years by 3.6% (Lleras-Muney 2001) • Income • People w/o high school educ & income <$10k were 2-3 x’s more likely to have functional limitations and poorer self-rated health
OTHER FACTORS AFFECTING HEALTH Sturm, Health Affairs 2002
Determinants of Infant Health Corman and Grossman, 1985
Determinants of Infant Health Corman and Grossman, 1985
Determinants of Infant Health • Does more schooling and the availability of more providers improve infant health? • Is the marginal productivity of more providers greater for blacks or whites?
Determinants of Infant Health • Why might the marginal productivities for blacks and whites differ? • The regressions have poor controls for income,health status, preferences, etc. which may be correlated with schooling and the availability of providers • If the marginal productivity for most factors is greater for blacks then whites, why isn’t the overall neonatal mortality rate lower for blacks than whites?
Marginal Productivity of Provider Services for Infant Health (1-mortality rate)% Blacks Whites Medical Care
Marginal Productivity of Provider Services for Infant Health (cont.) • For any given level of provider services, marginal productivity may be higher for blacks than whites • However, the level of services may be higher for whites than blacks • Knowing the shape of the total product curve is not enough. You must also know where you are on it
Health in the 50 States • One measure of health status in the population in the # of deaths (per 100,000 residents) from heart disease • Suppose we have data on deaths from heart disease and other population characteristics by state • See Excel Spreadsheet • What factors might explain death from HD? • Why?