790 likes | 828 Views
Utility and Happiness. Miles Kimball and Robert Willis University of Michigan http://www-personal.umich.edu/~mkimball/pdf/index.html. A Growing Economic Literature Uses Happiness Data. Provocative findings—see Layard’s Happiness Mostly focuses on the cross-section and the long-run trend.
E N D
Utility and Happiness Miles Kimball and Robert Willis University of Michigan http://www-personal.umich.edu/~mkimball/pdf/index.html
A Growing Economic Literature Uses Happiness Data • Provocative findings—see Layard’s Happiness • Mostly focuses on the cross-section and the long-run trend. • Motivations of the researchers: • to study the welfare implications of non-traded goods • to diagnose optimization mistakes and study welfare implications in contexts where choice behavior is potentially inconsistent. • Many other economists are skeptical: the theoretical status of happiness is unclear.
What is Happiness? • Flow utility? • The individual’s overall objective function? • The part of the individual’s objective function that abstracts from the desire to do one’s duty? • The individual’s objective function plus pleasure from memory? • None of the above?
Outline of Introduction • Distinguishing utility and happiness as a matter of logic. • Why we care about utility and happiness. • Why the relationship between them can’t be simple (short version). • Our take on the relationship between utility and happiness.
A. “Utility” and “Happiness” • Lifetime Utility = The extent to which people get what they want, where what they want is indicated by their choices. • Happiness (Current Affect) = How positive people’s feelings are at a given time.
B. Judging Individual Welfare • People’s own choices and feelings are the two non-paternalistic indicators we have for individual welfare(what makes an individual better off in the sense relevant for policy). • A priori, both seem useful.
C. The Easterlin Paradox and Hedonic Adaptation Taking both feelings and choices seriously runs into the difficulty that affect and utility seem to behave quite differently. • Easterlin Paradox: Measured utility trends strongly upwards, while measured happiness has little trend. • Hedonic Adaptation: Utility is affected permanently by permanent changes in external circumstances, but the effects on happiness seem shorter-lived.
D. The Relationship Between Happiness and Utility is Unresolved Existing work in Economics largely either • ignores happiness data, e.g.: “Happiness is irrelevant to Economics” OR B. assumes happiness=flow utility: “Happiness is a sufficient statistic for utility.”
The Middle Way In this paper, we steer a middle course between these two extremes: • Happiness ≠ Flow Utility, BUT • Happiness has a systematic relationship to utility.
The Question: What is the Relationship? • Both felt happiness and choice-based utility are well-defined, observable concepts. It is easy to resolve many seeming paradoxes when one recognizes that these are two different things. • Thenature of the relationship between the standard psychological concept of happiness (affect) and the standard economic concept of lifetime utility is an open empirical question.
Significance Establishing any systematic relationship between affect and utility would • provide an important bridge between psychologyandeconomics. • allow psychological data and theory to be used in economics in a way that is complementary to standard economic data and theory. • allow all the tools of economics to be brought to bear toward understanding happiness.
Sketch of our Integrated Theory of Utility and Happiness Experienced happiness is the sum of two components: • elation: short-run happiness that depends on recent news about lifetime utility • baseline mood: long-run happiness that is a subutility function (like health, entertainment, or nutrition.)
Why Happiness Matters for Economics (Our View) • First, short-run happiness in response to news can give important information about preferences. • Second, long-run happiness is important for economic welfare in the same way as other composite goods such as health, entertainment, or nutrition.
The Core of the Paper 3. Measuring Happiness 4. Measuring Utility 5. Utility ≠ Happiness: Evidence 6. An Integrated Theory of Utility and Happiness
Bonus Features 7. Why Utility and Happiness are Often Confused 8. Elation in the Utility Function 9. Implications for Happiness Empirics 10. Implications for Policy
3.Psychologists Reliably Measure Happiness, But What Is It? • Some economists think happiness can’t be measured well. This is just not true. Current happiness (affect) is one of the easiest of all subjective concepts to measure. • What is true (that these economists are intuiting) is that once happiness is measured, we don’t know what it means in terms of economic theory.
Measuring Current Happiness (‘Affect’). “Now think about the past week and the feelings you have experienced. Please tell me if each of the following was true for you much of the time this past week: • Much of the time during the past week, you felt you were happy. (Would you say yes or no)? • (Much of the time during the past week,) you felt sad. (Would you say yes or no?) • (Much of the time during the past week,) you enjoyed life. (Would you say yes or no?) • (Much of the time during the past week,) you felt depressed. (Would you say yes or no?)”
The Validity of Self-Reported Happiness Correlated with • frequency of smiling. • others’ ratings of how happy someone is. • social rank. • high activity in the left pre-frontal cortex and low activity in the right pre-frontal cortex--which can also be induced by seeing pictures of a smiling baby and reduced by seeing pictures of a deformed baby.
Other Measures of Subjective Well-Being: Life Satisfaction On a scale from 1 to 10, how satisfied are you with your life?
World Values Survey Global Happiness Question "Taking all things together, would you say you are • Very happy • Quite happy • Not very happy • Not at all happy 9. Don’t Know [Do NOT READ OUT]”
Judging overall life-satisfaction or overall happiness in life is a complex cognitive task. Evidence on the sensitivity of of subjective well-being data to context indicates that respondents use shortcuts involving readily accessible information, such as How happy the respondent feels right now How happy the respondent thinks he or she should feel, given objective circumstances. Problems with these Alternative Measures of Subjective Well-Being
Advantages of Affect Measures (Current Happiness Measures) • By contrast, affect measures depend on much more accessible information: • How R feels right now. • How R felt the past week. • Very little judgment is required. • How R feels right now affects the overall life-satisfaction or global happiness questions anyway. It is clearer to focus on that current happiness component directly. Then we know what we are getting.
4. Measuring Utility: Revealed Preference Over Choices • The Ordinalist, or “revealed preference” revolution in Economics developed techniques for measuring individual welfare based on choice data alone. • This clearly defines utility as a distinct concept from happiness. • Utility is the extent to which people get what they want. • Happiness is how people feel.
The Trend in Utility:Choose between 1955 and 2005 • The electronics revolution and the Internet have vastly expanded access to a rapidly growing quantity of culture and science. • Crime, teenage pregnancy and drug abuse worsened at first but now trend downward. • Greater equality between races and sexes. • War on Terror better than Cold War. • Better medical care and greater longevity.
Would you want to go back to the way things used to be? • No computers or electronics • No Ben and Jerry’s • No Harry Potter • No Beatles music yet released • Jim Crow, strong male dominance • Cold War • Few modern drugs
Do People Know Their Own Utility Functions? • Not perfectly. For example, I don’t know if I will like a new flavor of ice cream. • Lack of knowledge of one’s own utility function can be modeled as an internal informational constraint. (Rayo-Becker is an example.) • The key distinguishing features of mistakes about one’s own utility function are • regret • changing one’s mind after learning more.
Can Happiness Data Alone Diagnose Optimization Mistakes? • No. Happiness data alone cannot diagnose a mistake without strong assumptions about the relationship between utility and happiness. • Even the relevance of mistakes in predicting future happiness depends on the relationship between happiness and utility. • In Section 8 C, we illustrate how people could make mistakes in the impulse response pattern of future happiness without impairing optimization at all.
5. Happiness ≠ Flow Utility: Evidence • Assuming that current happiness is equal to flow utility immediately has many strong implications. • In particular, a large amount of data on happiness exists, with many characteristics that do not match usual ideas about utility. • Measured happiness • has no strong trend. • is strongly mean-reverting.
Hedonic Adaptation(Mean Reversion of Affect) Cross-sectional evidence of hedonic adaptation for • incarceration • loss of the use of limbs • serious burns • death of a spouse • winning the lottery • winning £10,000 raises affect by six times as much in the first year as £10,000 per year in additional income.
Experience Data Show Even Stronger Hedonic Adaptation • Data on felt happiness from experience sampling reverts to its previous level even more completely than life satisfaction and global happiness assessments (Kahneman and Schwartz, unpublished work). Why? • Life satisfaction and global happiness assessments incorporate • an element of autobiography • people’s ideas about how they “should” feel
Hedonic Adaptation is Not the Same Thing as Habit Formation • Hedonic adaptation is a statement about happiness, as measured by psychologists. • Habit formation is a statement about utility, as measured by economists. • If happiness were equal to flow utility, data on hedonic adaptation would imply very strong habit formation.
Evidence on Habit Formation Constantinides Form: 1. Joseph Lupton estimates θ≈.75 based on portfolio choices 2. Impulse responses for consumption choices suggest θ close to zero unless the lags in the habit H are very long.
Modeling Choice: Habit Formation or Just Hedonic Adaptation? Suppose and 1. Equivalent to and happiness=first difference of flow utility. 2. Let’s keep the economic theory simple and put the complexity in the utility-happiness relationship. a. It’s clearer and simpler. b. It avoids the misleading impression that there is anything wrong with the more traditional functional form.
Other Evidence that Utility≠Happiness 1. People make choices eagerly that they never regret, but which have no long-run effect on their affect. • Moving to a new city • Buying a nice car 2. With some misgivings at the tradeoff, people make choices that they never regret which lower their affect. • Commuting further to a higher-paying job. • Longer working hours to put one’s child through college.
6. Integrated Theory of Utility and Happinesshappiness= baseline mood + elation. A. Elation B. Baseline Mood C. Formal Model D. Expectations and Happiness E-G. Evolutionary Significance -Elation -Hedonic Adaptation -Baseline Mood H. Implications of the Integrated Theory
News andHappiness • The relationship between circumstances and happiness is weak in the long run, BUT • No one disputes that in the short run happiness responds in an intuitive way to news about lifetime utility. • Thus, we argue that an important component of happiness is due to recent news about lifetime utility.
‘Elation’ and ‘Dismay’ • ‘elation’ = the component of happiness due to recent news about lifetime utility. • ‘dismay’ = -elation
Elation and Hedonic Adaptation • If expectations are rational, standard results about rational expectations imply that elation will be strongly mean reverting. Intuitively, • News doesn’t stay news for very long. • The initial burst of elation dissipates once the full import of news is emotionally and cognitively processed. • Relevance to the Hedonic Treadmill, a.k.a. the Easterlin Paradox.
‘Baseline Mood’ • baseline mood = M(Kt, Xt) • Xt= vector of control variables: time use, spending pattern, portfolio choice, etc. • Kt = vector of • state variables encoding every aspect of the past that matters for utility: wealth, weight, habits, level of fatigue, one’s spouse being alive, etc. • variables exogenous to the individual: weather, state of macroeconomy, consumption patterns of others in society, etc. CONTINUED ON NEXT SLIDE →
Baseline Mood and Flow Utility • flow utility = U(Kt, Xt, M(Kt, Xt)) • We think of baseline mood M(Kt, Xt) as the component of happiness produced by a household production function. • A good analogy is to health. Like health, baseline mood • can be measured independently of Kt and Xt • is only one argument of the flow utility function • depends on different things than flow utility does (or on the same things with different weights) • has a complex household production function
What does Baseline Mood Depend on? • Any persistent aspect of happiness is part of baseline mood. Genes are the biggest factor. Also, there is some evidence that each of the following has a persistent effect on happiness: a. Prozac b. sleep c. exercise d. good eating habits e. social rank • + pleasantness of one’s current activity
Do People Know the Production Function for Baseline Mood? • Just as people don’t know the true production function for health, they may not know the true production function for baseline mood. • Lack of understanding of the dynamics of the elation mechanism could make it difficult for individuals to parcel out the determinants of baseline mood. • The discovery and dissemination of facts about the determinants of baseline mood could have large positive welfare effects • A big deal if the share of the money and time budget devoted to baseline mood trends up.
Applying Price Theory to Baseline Mood • Is baseline mood a luxury good? • Even normality of baseline mood leads to a version of the Easterlin Paradox: Why don’t people buy higher baseline mood as part of their expanding consumption bundle? • Two potential answers: • Some uptrending negative externalities may be particularly bad for baseline mood. • The relative price of baseline mood may be trending up. (A large effect if the elasticity of substitution between baseline mood and other goods is high.)
Formal Model of Utility and Happiness vt = lifetime utility U =flow utility M =baseline mood Et= rational expectation as of time t β = impatience Kt = state vector: wealth, weight, fatigue, being alive, spouse being alive, genes, weather, prices, tax rates, pollution average level of consumption in society… Xt = control vector: consumption, time use …
The Innovation in Lifetime Utility and Elation Note about the lifetime utility innovation:
Neurobiological Evidence that Expectations Matter for Affect • “These studies measured the firing of dopamine neurons in the animal’s ventral striatum, which is known to play a powerful role in motivation and action. • In their paradigm, a tone was sounded, and two seconds later a juice reward was squirted into the monkey’s mouth. • Initially, the neurons did not fire until the juice was delivered.
Neurobiological Evidence that Expectations Matter for Affect • Once the animal learned that the tone forecasted the arrival of juice two seconds later, however, the same neurons fired at the sound of the tone, but did not fire when the juice reward arrived. • These neurons were not responding to reward, or its absence … they were responding to deviations from expectations. • When the juice was expected from the tone, but was not delivered, the neurons fired at a very low rate, as if expressing disappointment.” (p.26)