250 likes | 406 Views
Lowering Barriers to Cost-Effective Restoration. Lisa A. Wainger, PhD University of Maryland Center for Environmental Science US EPA Office of Research & Development. The Costs and Benefit Analysis What are the best assumptions?. Mix of practices affects costs & benefits
E N D
Lowering Barriers to Cost-Effective Restoration Lisa A. Wainger, PhD University of Maryland Center for Environmental Science US EPA Office of Research & Development
The Costs and Benefit AnalysisWhat are the best assumptions? • Mix of practices affects costs & benefits • Site and landscape features affect costs, effectiveness & benefits • Ecosystem services included / excluded from analysis affect benefit estimates • Program implementation choices affect costs
Acknowledgements Analysis primarily drawn from soon to be released report: An Optimization Approach to Evaluate the Role of Ecosystem Services in Chesapeake Bay Restoration Strategies Analysis Team • RTI International – Marion Deerhake, George Van Houtven, Robert Beach, Ross Loomis, Mike Gallaher, Dallas Wood • AbtAssocates – Isabelle Morin, Lauren Praesel, ViktoriaZoltay, David Mitchell, Ryan Stapler, Elena Besedin • EPA Office of Research and Development – Jay Messer, Lisa Wainger, Rob Wolcott, Andrew Almeter • Many others contributed ideas, data and information
Optimization Approach Key Questions • What mix of pollution-control projects provides the least cost way to achieve water quality goals in an impaired watershed • How does the consideration of “bonus” ecosystem services affect the desired mix of projects?
Summary of Optimization Analysis • Establish cost-effectiveness of grey & green practices • Evaluate availability of acres for implementation of green practices • Develop ecological production functions and benefit functions to value ecosystem services • Optimize to select the least-cost mix of practices meeting all 3 TMDL targets with / without bonus ecosystem services • Analyze sensitivity to assumptions • Quantify cost savings and ecosystem service benefits of alternatives
Some Important Caveats • Analysis assumptions only partially constrained by current rules and policies • Not a comprehensive set of BMPs – e.g., missing CAFOs, erosion control practices • Not a comprehensive set of monetized benefits • Benefit transfer does not consider changes in supply vs demand ≠ WTP • Does not represent all social tradeoffs of choices; does not represent policy recommendations • Short-term project = reliance on readily available data; intermediate level of model detail
Grey and Green Management / Restoration Practices Included Point Source BMPs POTW Advanced Nutrient Removal Industrial Advanced Nutrient Removal Nonpoint Source Urban Stormwater BMPs Extended Detention Ponds Bio-retention Planters Urban Forest Buffers Urban Grass Buffers Urban Wetlands Nonpoint Source Agricultural BMPs Forest Riparian Buffers Grass Riparian Buffers Conversion to Forest Land Retirement Livestock Exclusion Restored Wetlands Winter Cover Crops No-Till Agriculture Payment for Reducing Fertilizer Application (AFT)
What we know: Cost-Effectiveness of BMPs Varies by Location Source: TMDL Executive Summary Nitrogen runoff effect on Bay mainstem habitat quality by watershed
Basin factors Variable runoff rates (county) Variable BMP removal effectiveness (GM region) Attenuation factors Variable nutrient delivery to Bay by location (HUC) “Effectiveness” factor based on Bay residence time (HUC) Cost Factors Opportunity costs = rental rates (state) Direct implementation costs = reimbursements (county/state) Availability of implementation locations (HUC) How much spatial variability of costs did we capture with readily available data?
Optimization ResultsCost-effective Locations of Nitrogen & Sediment Reductions by Land-River Segment (Base Case)
Marginal Cost Curve for Achieving N target in Susquehanna Basin N reduction goal = 33.14 M lbs
Spatially Averaged Unit Costs Conceal Management Opportunities Diminishing Marginal Returns Economies of scale Marginal Cost ($) (cost of the last unit of nutrient reduction) E3 0 Total Nutrient Reduction from 1985 Baseline
The Geography of Ecosystem Service Benefits • Where do benefits accrue? headwaters - oceans • How effective is the restoration? • How many ecosystem services “users” are affected? • How much is each service user affected? • sensitivity to environmental change • substitutability
Estuarine and Near-Shore Benefits of Chesapeake Bay TMDLs TMDLs designed to protect: Resulting water-quality related Ecosystem Service Benefits: Health and safety (+air) Recreational opportunities (swimming, boating, fishing) Commercial fishing Visual and olfactory aesthetics Property value support Non-use benefits of aquatic species / ecosystems Water treatment cost savings • Migratory fish spawning and nursery • Shallow-water Bay grass • Open-water fish and shellfish • Deep-water seasonal fish and shellfish • Deep-channel seasonal refuge
Terrestrial and Upstream Ecosystem Service Benefits (Bonus ES) • Recreational opportunities - (waterfowl hunting, game hunting, trout fishing, birding, hiking, upstream boating) • Aesthetic benefits - (open space, freshwater quality) • Health(air quality improvements) • Property value support (non-Bay adjacent) • Flood risk reduction • Climate change risk mitigation (carbon sequestration, GHGs) • Amenity-derived economic support • Educational support (distributed natural sites) • Non-use benefits of species and ecosystems (bog turtle, brook trout) Red = Valued in optimization analysis
Sources of Benefit Uncertainty: Restoration / BMP Effectiveness 50 Poor Sub- Optimal Optimal Marginal % Sites / Permits 0 100 0 Wetland Assessment Score Ambrose, et al. 2006
Optimization Results Cost Offsets from Ecosystem ServicesAlternative Scenarios: Base Case & 3a (2:1 offset ratios) $1.46 B/yr $1.17 B/yr $1.49 B/yr $1.16 B/yr $218 M/yr $90 M/yr $301 M/yr $63 M/yr Both Scenarios: Basin level load reductions & 10% transaction costs on offsets Base Case 3a Base Case 3a
Summary of Cost Offsets from Ecosystem Service Benefits • For the “base case” bonus ecosystem services return at least $90M/yr of the $218M/yr gross costs to achieve the TMDL • The least net cost solution increases those costs to $310 M/yr, but reduces the net social costs from $128 to $63 M/yr • Butsolutionswould result in retirement of approximately 1.7 M acres of working ag land (including half of the cropland in the basin)
Value of competing services inform tradeoffs Public Ecosystem Services B A Private Crop Yields
Other ResultsCost of TMDL Compliance (N loads only) by Geography of Trading Area million $
Fine-scale allocation of load reductions reduces ability of credit buyers to find low-cost sellers Source: TMDL Executive Summary Nitrogen runoff effect on Bay mainstem habitat quality by watershed
Non-monetized co-benefits • The EO targets restoring 58sub-watersheds to healthy status for brook trout – the base scenario restores 122 sub-watersheds. • The 30,000 acre wetland EO strategic target could be met for an additional $6 M/yr or 3% of estimated costs.
Improving benefit assessmentsIdentifying wherechanges in supply are likely to generate benefits Benefit / Utility (population viability) Non-use service benefits are enhanced by improvements in conservation status 30% % native range preserved
$X + $238 M $X $300 M Improved Efficiency from Joint Production of Multiple Ecosystem Service Benefits As Suggested by Optimization Analysis Benefits Upstream + Downstream Benefits Downstream Benefits Only 0 TMDL Program costs
Conclusions Benefits • Jointproduction of upstream + downstream ecosystem services could reduce net program costs • Simple analysis suggests ~40% of costs offset (base case) • Quantifying potential changes in ESbenefitsthat can’t be monetized augments the benefits picture Costs • Accounting for performance risk greatly increases costs (high model sensitivity to offset/trading ratios) • TMDL Program rules can affect costs (e.g., largerareas for offset / trading arelikely to reduce costs) • Unit costs can be misleading if they hide economies of scale and diminishing marginal returns